DOES CHINA NEED A MORE FLEXIBLE EXCHANGE RATE? by TengT. Xu B.A., Acadia University, 2006 PROJECT SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS IN DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF NORTHERN BRITISH COLUMBIA September 2011 © Teng T. Xu, 2011 UNIVERSITY of NORTHERN BRITISH COLUMBIA LIBRARY Prince George, B.C. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY During the past few years, there has been heated debate-both domestically and internationally-about China's exchange rate policy. At the heart of the debate are two fundamental issues: First, is the renminbi undervalued? If so, by how much; and second, toward what exchange rate regime should China move? This paper sheds light on the first issue by examining the "equilibrium" value of the renminbi and its alleged undervaluation, but focuses on the second issue- in particular, the risks to financial stability and the domestic costs of China's current exchange rate regime. By reviewing a large number of Chinese and western literatures on a series of specific issues pertaining to China's exchange rate policy such as: the revolution of the renminbi exchange rate regime since the start of the economic reforms 30 plus years ago; the "equilibrium" value of the renminbi and its alleged undervaluation; China's fast growing current account surplus in recent years and its contributing factors; the risks to financial stability and other domestic costs of China's current rigid exchange rate regime, this paper finds that the latest debates on the renminbi exchange rate regime in China mirror those in the west. In other words, there are same rival camps both inside and outside China. The synthesis of their findings is that greater exchange rate flexibility can resolve many of the challenges and obstacles posed by China's current tightly managed exchange rate regime. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS Executive Summary ......................................................................................... ii Table of Contents ............................................................................................ iii List of Figures ................................................................................................ iv Acknowledgement ........................................................................................... v Chapter 1. Introduction and Preview ......................................................................... 1 2. China's Exchange Rate Regimes Since the Late 1970s ...................................... 7 2.1 Moving Toward A More Market-Based Exchange Rate Regime (1979-1994) ......... 7 2.2 De Facto Pegged Exchange Rate Regime (1994-2005) .................................. 10 2.3 New Managed Floating Exchange Rate Regime (Post 2005) ............................ 11 3. Renminhi's Equilibrium Exchange Rate and Its Alleged Undervaluation ............ 14 4. China's Extraordinarily Large Current Account Surplus and Its Determinants ... 21 4.1 The Upsurge in China's Current Account Surplus in Recent Years ..................... 21 4.2 Capital-Intensive, Industry-Led Growth with High Domestic Savings and Investment ........................................................................................... 23 4.3 Total Factor Productivity Improvements .................................................... 26 4.4 Factor Market Distortions ..................................................................... 28 a) Distortions in the Labor Market ....................................................... 28 b) Distortions in the Market for Land, Energy, and Primary Commodities ....... 30 4.5 Exchange Rate Distortion and Policies Promoting Export Growths ..................... 33 5. Conundrums Facing the Chinese Authorities Under the Current Exchange Rate Regime ............................................................................................... 38 5.1 Monetary Policy Independence ............................................................... 38 5.2 China's Large Hoarding of Foreign Exchange Reserves .................................. 41 5.3 Banking Sector Reforms ....................................................................... 43 5.4 Rebalancing ofthe Chinese Economy ....................................................... 44 6. Concluding Remarks ............................................................................. 46 References .................................................................................................... 52 iii LIST OF FIGURES FIGURE PAGE Figure 2.1: Dual (Nominal US Dollar) Exchange Rates of the Renminbi, 1981-1994 .. ..... .. 10 Figure 2.2: Nominal US Dollar Exchange Rate of the Renminbi, 1994-2005 ........ .... ....... 11 Figure 2.3: China Balance of Trade ............. ... ........ ..... ... .... ..... ....... ......... ........ .. 13 Figure 2.4: Nominal US Dollar Exchange Rate of the Renminbi, Post 2005 ........ ........... . 14 Figure 4.1: China' s Current Account Position(% GDP), 1985-2009 ....... .. ..... ......... .... . 21 Figure 4.2: China' s Real Effective Exchange Rate, 1994Q1-2008Q2 ...... ... .. ..... ... ........ 34 iv ACHNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to acknowledge appreciation for the support of my graduate supervisor, Dr. Paul Bowles. I would like to thank him sincerely for his insightful advice and guidance, and for his boundless generosity and patience toward me. I would also like to thank my friends and family, in particular my mother for supporting and inspiring me to stick to my dreams. v CHAPTER 1- INTRODUCTION AND PREVIEW Since its opening up to the outside world and the series of economic reforms it started to adopt in the late 1970s, China's economic performance has been one of the strongest in history with annual gross domestic product (GOP) growth averaging nearly 10 percent over the 1980-2010 period, compared to 4.5 percent for all emerging and developing economies over the same period (IMF, 2011).1 Although the country's per capita income is still modest at USD$3,678 in 2009 (World Bank, 2011), with almost one fifth of the world's population, China surpassed Japan as the world's second-largest economy after the United States by both nominal GOP and by purchasing power parity (PPP) in the second quarter of 2010, according to a well-known economist with the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (CASS) named Ming Zhang (2010a). Following three decades of rapid economic expansion, China has also become the second largest trading nation in the world and the largest exporter and second largest importer of goods. The package of macroeconomic and structural policy reforms that has generated this growth has clearly worked well for China. Nevertheless, the Chinese authorities need to deal with a much more complicated economic situation than ever before as the country is facing macroeconomic, social and environmental challenges that have their origin in its pattern of growth. Together with other structural reforms that have opened up the Chinese economy to foreign investment and trade, a tightly managed exchange rate regime has been one important part of a development strategy that promotes export-led economic growth in China over the past three decades or so. Since the late 1970s and prior to 2005, as China's 1 Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database for April 2011 and author's own calculations. 1 economic reforms and liberalization process moved forward, its exchange rate regime had gradually evolved from a "centrally planned administrative mechanism to a dual-rate system, then to a managed float with a narrow band, and finally to a managed float with a very narrow band-a de facto peg to the [U.S.] dollar" (Huang & Wang, 2004, p.337). According to Zhichao Zhang (2000), with the deepening of market-oriented reforms in the mid-1980s, the exchange rate was for the first time recognized by the Chinese authorities as an "economic lever" that should be applied to promote exports. That is also when exchange rate reform was first launched in China. In July 2005, the renminbi's decade long peg to the U.S. dollar was formally changed when China launched a much-heralded currency reform. However, despite pledges by the Chinese authorities in recent years to increase the role of market forces in the determination of the renminbi exchange rate, and to manage a floating exchange rate against a basket of currencies rather than the U.S. dollar alone, in practice, the renminbi still appears to be pegged to the dollar, with little flexibility. During the past few years, there has been heated debate-both domestically and internationally-about China's exchange rate policy. At the heart of the debate are two fundamental issues: First, is the renminbi undervalued? If so, by how much; and second, toward what exchange rate regime should China move? This paper sheds light on the first issue by examining the "equilibrium" value of the renminbi and its alleged undervaluation, but focuses on the second issue-in particular, the risks to financial stability and the domestic costs of China's current exchange rate regime. By reviewing a large number of articles on a series of specific issues pertaining to China's exchange rate policy such as: the revolution of the renminbi exchange rate regime since the start of the economic reforms 30 plus years ago; the "equilibrium" value of the renminbi and its alleged undervaluation; 2 China's fast growing current account surplus in recent years and its contributing factors; the risks to financial stability and other domestic costs of China's current rigid exchange rate regime, this paper aims to synthesize findings by analysts and policymakers from both inside and outside China (some written in Chinese) and act as the culmination of a study of the latest debate on China's exchange rate policy. At the current stage of development, China needs to employ monetary policy to accommodate some broad objectives such as price stability, balanced balance-of-payments (BOP) account, and sustainable economic growth. Since the effective management of the renminbi exchange rate system could help China's economy achieve all these macroeconomic objectives and have an impact on the country's competitiveness, trade relations and resources allocation, the question of an equilibrium exchange rate has been a major source of concern among analysts and policymakers during the current debate on China's exchange rate policy. The mismanagement of the renminbi exchange rate regime along with a misaligned renminbi, on the other hand, could negatively influence the stability of China's financial system, possibly resulting in regional and even global financial crises. However, according to Morris Goldstein and Nicholas Lardy (2008, p.3), "[a]ny methodology that defines the equilibrium exchange rate for the renminbi as the real effective exchange rate 2 (REER) that would produce 'balance' in China's global current account position, or in its basic balance, or in its overall [BOP] position, yields the 2 An "effective" exchange rate index is a weighted average of the country's exchange rate against its major trading partners, where the weights on individual currencies are typically related to the importance of that country in the home country's trade. A "real" exchange rate index adjusts movements in the nominal exchange rate for differences in inflation rates between the home and foreign country, since higher inflation represents a decline in price competitiveness just like an appreciation of the home currency. A "real effective" exchange rate index combines these two features (Goldstein, 2007). 3 qualitative conclusion that the renminbi is significantly undervalued and probably by an increasing margin over time." In an effort to keep the renminbi from appreciating, the Chinese authorities have been engaging in large-scale, one-way intervention in the foreign exchange market for many years. The excessive expansion of China's current account surplus that has accompanied, among other factors, the increasingly undervalued renminbi exchange rate, along with the continuous blocking of a renminbi appreciation large enough to substantially reduce China's current account surplus, not only imposes a constraint on the country's monetary policy, with increasing risk to the banking and the financial system, but also makes it much harder for China to move to a more balanced and sustainable growth path. First, a rigid exchange rate regime compounded by a large current account surplus substantially reduces the independence of monetary policy. In recent years, the growth in China's current account surplus-which is a by-product of the distinct features of China's pattern of growth and a variety of policies that are behind it, including, perhaps crucially, exchange rate policy-has reached unprecedented levels. Normally, a large expansion of current account surplus would lead to appreciation pressures on the domestic currency, which in turn would lead to deterioration in the country's competitive position in international trade. However, resisting pressures for renminbi appreciation, the People's Bank of China (PBOC), China's central bank, purchases a large amount of foreign exchange. Such rigid exchange rate arrangement fuels a surge in the supply of base money and generates a "liquidity overhang" in the Chinese banking system. At the current juncture, relatively high domestic interest rates would be needed to cool down the "overheated" economy and to prevent risks of hyperinflation. However, the paradox is that higher 4 interest rates would trigger speculative capital inflows, which in turn would put more upward pressures on the renminbi exchange rate. Moreover, China's massive intervention in the foreign exchange market has resulted in the accumulation of a large hoarding of foreign exchange reserves reaching USD$3.04 trillion in March 2011, according to figures released by the central bank 3 (PBOC, 2011), mainly in the forms of U.S. dollars and U.S. dollar-denominated assets give a number here for the reserve holdings that puts the country at risk for potential capital losses in the event of U.S. dollar depreciation. Next, China's current exchange rate arrangement given its extraordinarily large foreign exchange reserves has negative implications for the profitability and efficiency of the domestic banking system, which in turn may hamper banking sector reforms. In order to prevent any large movement of the renminbi exchange rate, the PBOC intervenes massively in the foreign exchange market. This in turn increases the supply of monetary aggregates and thus generates excessive liquidity in the Chinese banking system. The PBOC is then forced to engage in large-scale, open-market sterilization operations to keep domestic inflation at bay. Such sterilization operations are normally carried out through non-market oriented tools including low-yielding sterilization bonds issued by the PBOC, administrative controls on bank lending and credit expansion, as well as moral suasion. However, the accumulating large stocks of low-yielding, non-performing liquid instruments on the balance sheets of commercial banks raise concerns over bank profitability as "the true cost of sterilization is partly transferred off the balance sheet of the central bank and onto the balance sheet of the banking system" (Cappiello & Ferrucci, 2008, p.8). In addition, 3 According to Cappiello and Ferrucci (2008, p.16), "China's stock of foreign exchange reserves has grown around eightfold since the beginning of 2000, to USD$1,202 billion in March-the largest stock in the world, equivalent to around 46 percent of GDP." At the end of that year, the country's total foreign exchange reserves reached USD$1,530 billion, close to 50 percent of GDP (PBOC, 2008). 5 according to David Dollar and Shang-Jin Wei (2007), as commercial banks are constrained by the monetary authority to provide cheap credit to inefficient state enterprises, especially in the export sector, large distortion and efficiency costs have been incurred as a result. Lastly, a rigid exchange rate regime vitiates China's efforts to rebalance the sources of its economic growth and make it more sustainable in the long run. Over the past decade or so, China's exceptionally rapid economic growth has relied heavily on manufacturing, external demand, and investment. While the reliance on manufacturing exports in urban China has become a growing burden on the environment, overinvestment and the resultant accumulation of capital in urban industry has led to widening productivity differences, and therefore income inequality, between urban and rural areas (Hofman & Kuijs, 2007). On the one hand, these imbalances all appear linked, inter alios, to China's tightly managed exchange rate regime. On the other hand, a more flexible renminbi exchange rate that is increasingly driven by market forces can contribute to the country's desired transition to a more equitable and environmentally sustainable growth path by reducing the profitability and competitiveness of Chinese exports, and by allowing monetary authorities to raise domestic interest rates to moderate investment booms in the urban manufacturing export industry-both of which would translate into reduced export growth in China. As a result, this paper advocates greater flexibility in the renminbi exchange rate regime and thus faster revaluation of the renminbi for the sake of China's own interests. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Chapter 2 explores the evolution of China's de facto exchange rate regime since the late 1970s in the context of its development strategy. Chapter 3 examines the renminbi's alleged undervaluation by providing an overview of the 6 different estimates of its equilibrium REER. Chapter 4 analyses China's current account surplus and its determinants. Chapter 5 discusses the key challenges facing the Chinese authorities under the existing currency regime, and makes the case for greater flexibility in the renminbi exchange rate. Chapter 6 offers some concluding remarks on what can and should be done to accelerate China's exchange rate reform. CHAPTER 2- CHINA'S EXCHANGE RATE REGIMES SINCE THE LATE 1970S 2.1 Moving Toward A More Market-Based Exchange Rate Regime (1979-1994) In the late 1970s, China contemplated its exchange rate reform for the first time when general economic reforms and liberalization process focused on increasing foreign trade and investment were adopted by the ruling Communist Party of China. Since a country's choice of an appropriate exchange rate regime-be it fixed, floating, or intermediate-can affect its macroeconomic performance such as inflation, cross-border trade and capital flows, etc., exchange rate policy in China has since been regarded as a matter of exceptional importance. This, however, was not true before 1978 when China first launched its economic reforms and open-door policy. According to Zhang (2000), throughout its system of economic planning from the late 1940s to the late 1970s, market forces had virtually no role in China's administrative exchange rate arrangements. "It was a mere accounting device linking foreign trade and the domestic economy" (Zhang, 2000, p.1076). Moreover, changes in the exchange rate could not affect directly China's overall balance of payments as the volumes of trade and financial flows were fixed by the central government as part of the country's import-substitution industrialization strategy. "The transformation of the role, adjustment rules, and the institutional arrangement of the renminbi exchange rate since the late 1970s has been successful in bringing 7 'economic realism' to China's official exchange rate which was previously considered economically meaningless" (Wu & Chen, 1992, p.37). According to Dilip Das (2008), taking lessons from its dynamic Asian neighbors, the Chinese authorities soon decided to abandon its strategy of keeping the currency overvalued for the simple reason that a competitively priced renminbi was imperative for adopting an export-led growth strategy like that in Japan and other high-performing Asian economies. This in fact explains why in the post 1978 period the renminbi exchange rate, which had long been fixed at overvalued levels, was devalued repeatedly over a long period of time as economic policies became increasingly pro-trade (Das, 2008). In early 1981, in an effort to improve the profitability of exporters and the competitiveness of Chinese exports in the global market place, the PBOC conducted a major exchange rate reform exercise in which a dual exchange rate system was introduced-that is, the official exchange rate coexisted with a market-determined, trade-related internal settlement rate. According to Goldstein and Lardy (2009), at that point the official rate was RMB1.5 to the dollar, so the internal settlement rate of RMB2.8 was a devaluation of almost 100 percent. Whereas the official rate was adjusted periodically in response to changes in the value of a basket of currencies and was used mainly to cover non-trade, service-related transactions such as overseas Chinese remittances, tourism, etc., the internal settlement rate was pegged exclusively do the U.S. dollar and was applied to all current account transactions (Goldstein & Lardy, 2009). Over the next few years, the official exchange rate was further devalued. It eventually unified with the internal settlement rate on January 1, 1985 when the PBOC formally abandoned the latter (Goldstein & Lardy, 2009). In 1986, however, a dual 8 exchange rate system re-emerged in China with the establishment of Foreign Exchange Adjustment Centers or "swap centers" (Das, 2008). As Das (2008) expounds, under this new dual-track system, the official exchange rate coexisted with a market-driven, swap center rate that was "depreciating over time in response to economic fundamentals." Foreign investors along with domestic enterprises in the four Special Economic Zones namely Shantou, Shenzhen, Xiamen and Zhuhai, were permitted to trade foreign exchange on the basis of negotiations between sellers and buyers at over 100 swap centers nationwide. And by 1988, all Chinese enterprises with foreign exchange earnings were allowed to make use of the swap center rates (Das, 2008). As economic liberalization and the opening-up process accelerated in the late 1980s, the PBOC progressively devalued the official rate in an effort to close the gap between it and the market rates. According to Lardy (2002), in a single step on July 5, 1986, the official rate depreciated by 15 percent to RMB3. 7 per dollar from its mid-1986 rate of RMB3.2. A further devaluation in December 1989 took the official rate to RMB4. 7 per dollar. In 1991, the Chinese authorities summarized the objectives of the renminbi exchange rate reform as: (1) rationalizing the level of the exchange rate and (2) making full play of the exchange rate as an economic lever that should be applied to promote exports (Yin et al., 1991). Over the next four years, the PBOC continued to devalue the official renminbi exchange rate until it reached RMB5.8 per dollar at year-end 1993 (Lardy, 2002). Figure 2.1 plots the nominal US dollar exchange rate of the renminbi for the period 1981 to 1994. 9 Figure 2 .1 Dual (Nom inal US dollar) Exchang e Rates of the Renm inb i. 1981- 199 4 : ~ - - - OltQOI A ale o----- Secondary Rate I 71 ' [ 6~ 5· 1980 1990 1 99~ So u rce: Zhang (2000, pl071) 2.2 De Facto Pegged Exchange Rate Regime (1994-2005) On January 1, 1994, a major revamp of China's exchange rate system was carried out when the official exchange rate was devalued further to unify with the prevailing swap rate of RM88. 7 per dollar4 (Das, 2006). In other words, the dual exchange rate system in China was formally abandoned. At the same time, the Chinese monetary authorities introduced a unified, managed floating exchange rate regime with a narrow band of ±0.3 percent around the reference rate set by the PBOC for interbank transactions (Yi, 2008). Under the new structure, the renminbi exchange rate was revalued until it reached RMB8.3 per dollar in June 1995, and then slowly moved to RMB8.28 by October 1997 (Huang & Wang, 2004 ). However, from that time up to the new renminbi exchange rate reform initiated on July 21, 2005, the nominal value of the renminbi vis-a-vis the U.S. dollar was actually allowed to fluctuate within a margin of less than ±1 percent around the de facto fixed rate ofRM88.28, as noted by Yi (2008). Thus, albeit China claimed to have a managed floating renminbi exchange rate during that period, it "essentially operated its exchange rate system as a de 4 According to Das (2006), the official exchange rate jumped from RMBS.S to the dollar to RMB8. 7 which amounted to a devaluation of 32.09 percent in nominal terms. 10 facto peg to the U.S. dollar" (Das, 2008, p.61). Figure 2.2 plots the nominal US dollar exchange rate of the renminbi for the period 1994 to 2005. Figure 2 .2 Nominal US Dollar Ex change Rate of the Renminbi , 1994- 2005 9 .0 8 .0 Ill a ul :::S ~ I ....... . . . . . . . . . ·--....... 7.0 6 .0 5 .0 4 .0 3 .0 2 .0 1 .0 Tim e Period Source: Inte rnationa l Moneary Fund (2008) . IMF Onte rnat i ona l Financ ial Statistics, IF S In fact, expounds Das (2008, p.59), the option for a de facto U.S. dollar peg during the 1997-2005 period was regarded by the Chinese authorities as "an essential factor for vitalizing the external sector." The overarching feature of China's exchange rate reform thus far corroborated the fact that a relatively higher weight had been attributed to external competitiveness in its objective function (Zhang, 2000). As the renminbi-U.S. dollar bilateral exchange rate remained normally stable during that period despite rapid real GDP growth, rising total factor productivity, robust export expansion and massive foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows-all these factors would theoretically lead to currency appreciation, China's exports were given a substantive competitive advantage in relation to other exporting economies. 2.3 New Managed Floating Exchange Rate Regime (Post 2005) 11 The decade-long fixed nominal exchange rate of the renminbi vis-a-vis the U.S. dollar had served the Chinese economy well-in particular the export sector. However, in recent years, it has, along with other factors, contributed to huge internal and external imbalances in the country. For example, according to Goldstein and Lardy (2009), in 2008 China's current account surplus stood at USD$426 billion or 9.8 percent of the preliminary GDP announced by the government in January 2009 (see figure 4.1). The increase of USD$54 billion compared with 2007 was primarily due to the increase in the trade surplus (Goldstein & Lardy, 2009). Figure 2.3 displays China's balance oftrade from 2005 to 2008. Faced with increasing pressures to move toward a more flexible exchange rate regime and to let the renminbi appreciate monotonically in accordance with market forces, the PBOC on July 21, 2005 introduced a new managed float exchange rate system with reference to a basket of currencies rather than the U.S. dollar alone. Most importantly, the PBOC said that the renminbi exchange rate was to become more flexible with its value based more on market supply and demand (PBOC, 2005). According to Goldstein and Lardy (2008), under the new renminbi exchange rate regime, the official renminbi-U.S. dollar nominal exchange rate was immediately adjusted from RMB8.28 to RMB8.11 to the dollar, amounting to a 2.1 percent appreciation against the dollar. By the end of 2008, the nominal renminbi-U.S. dollar exchange rate was RMB6.83, reflecting a cumulative appreciation of 21 percent compared with that in July 2005 (Goldstein & Lardy, 2008). 12 Figure 2.3 CHINA BA LAN CE OF TRA DE ~ Jul / 05 Jan /0 6 :f Jul/0 6 ~ ~ :- .. :;J Jan /0 7 Jul / 07 Jan / 08 Source: TradingEconomics.com; General Admin istration of Custom Turning from the size and variability of renminbi exchange rate changes to the "basket" characteristics of China post-2005 currency regime, Frankel and Wei (2007) found that the renminbi continued to trace the U.S. dollar. In other words, only a limited degree of flexibility was introduced as a result of the exchange rate reforms of July 21, 2005. On August 10, 2005, for example, the PBOC published the currencies which made up the currency basket. It included the U.S. dollar, the euro, the Japanese yen and the Korean won as the four first tier currencies that have the largest weights. Albeit the weight of each individual currency, which reflected China's geographical distribution of trade, services, and capital flows, has been kept confidential, it is not difficult to imagine that the U.S. dollar heavily dominated the weights in the currency basket (Das, 2008). Since the onset of the global financial crisis in late 2008, however, the PBOC effectively re-pegged the renminbi near 6.83 per dollar to provide stability to its export sector in light of weakened external demand. As the recovery and upturn of the Chinese economy became more solid a couple of years later, the PBOC said on June 20, 2010-just one week before the G-20 meeting in Toronto-that it would proceed further with its currency reform by allowing more flexibility in the renminbi exchange rate, despite the fact 13 that no timeframe for the change was given. For example, in a Chinese articled published in International Finance in August 2010, economist Sibo Wang (2010) points out that since the PBOC announced the restart of the renminbi exchange rate regime reform a month ago, the nominal RMB-USD bilateral exchange rate has experienced rapid appreciation only in the initial stage and two-way fluctuations after that. Wang (2010)'s article examines from two aspects the trend of the renminbi exchange rate during this period: the flexibility of the renminbi exchange rate in relation to the currency basket and the speed of the renminbi appreciation on the initiative, discovering that the renminbi has in fact not appreciated on the initiative. In addition, the PBOC ruled out a one-time revaluation of the renminbi by saying that there was no basis for a large-scale appreciation, and kept the renminbi's 0.5 percent daily trading band against the U.S. dollar unchanged. Figure 2.3 plots the nominal US dollar exchange rate of the renminbi for the post 2005 period. Figure 2.4 Nominal US Dollar Exchange Rate of the Renminbi. Post 2005 8 .2 8 7 .8 7 .6 7.4 7 .2 7 6 .8 6 .6 6.4 2005-07-21 2006-04-28 2007-02-08 2007-11-23 2008-09-02 2009-06-19 2010-03-31 2011-01-12 Source: People's Bank of China, 2011 CHAPTER 3- RENMINBI'S EQUILIBRIUM EXCHANGE RATE AND ITS ALLEGED UNDERVALUATION 14 The historical account going back to the late 1970s summarized in the last chapter give us insights into Chinese policymakers' mentality behind managing the country's rigid exchange rate regime in the economic reform and opening-up era. The trends of the nominal RMB-USD bilateral exchange rate since the start of the reform 30 plus years ago, especially prior to the July 2005 exchange rate reform, indicate the nominal renminbi exchange rate has been heavily-manipulated by the Chinese authorities to implement an export-led growth strategy. Over the past few years, monetary authorities in China have been set against any dramatic changes in their currency regime due in large part to apprehension that a sharp renminbi appreciation would seriously destabilize the country's current export-led growth trajectory. As a result, the renminbi has been kept from appreciating by massive intervention in the international exchange market. Such intervention in tandem with China's sustained high export growth and a burgeoning current account surplus hitting a peak of 11 percent of GOP in 2007 (Batson, 2010), indicates an undervalued renminbi and that "[the] appreciation of the renminbi that has taken place to date against the U.S. dollar is completely inadequate to make a real dent in China's huge current account surplus" (Goldstein, 2007, p.2). Using different measurement approaches such as the Purchasing Power Parity (PPP), Behavioral Equilibrium Exchange Rate (BEER), and the Fundamental Equilibrium Exchange Rate (FEER), a good number of empirical studies have been undertaken to examine whether accusations of an undervalued renminbi can hold. However, by how much the renminbi is undervalued was, and continues to be, an area of complete disagreement in international monetary economics. This, according to Das (2009, p.574) is partly due to the fact that "which [methodology] is appropriate for the purpose of sizing up 15 the undervaluation of the [renminbi] has remained an unresolved issue until the present time." The first approach to identify the renminbi's equilibrium exchange rate is, according to William Cline and John Williamson (2007, p.3), "to find the exchange rate that would lead to purchasing power parity (PPP)." The PPP approach is perhaps one of the earliest approaches to determining the equilibrium exchange rates. It provides the long-run framework for the monetary and portfolio approaches to exchange rate determination. However, economists such as Cline and Williamson (2007) are skeptical of the PPP approach in general and its application to China in particular. "One major limitation of the approach," according to Cline and Williamson (2007, p.4), "is that by definition it means the United States can never be over- or undervalued: the United States is the numeraire for PPP exchange rate equal to market rate. This is a gaping hole for an analytical approach, considering that the US current account deficit currently absorbs the vast bulk of combined surpluses of the rest of the world." According to the Big Max index of The Economist, which falls squarely into the PPP category, the value of the renminbi to the dollar was 58 percent undervalued in 2007 (The Economist, 2007a). However, according to another analogous index called the "Starbucks talllatte index", the renminbi was only 1 percent undervalued in 2004 (Das, 2009). The second approach is the BEER developed by Peter Clark and Ronald MacDonald (1999). According to Cline and Williamson (2007, p.6), "A [BEER] aims to estimate the index level to which the market exchange rate might be expected to revert in the medium or long run, given an absence of shocks." Unlike PPP, which deals in direct price comparisons for internationally comparable baskets of goods, and in a similar fashion than 16 the FEER (which will be discussed later), the BEER explains the real exchange rate behavior in terms of economic fundamentals using reduced-form econometric equations. It focuses on the real exchange rate and the medium-term equilibrium rates of the fundamental determinants (i.e. internal and external balance proxies). In particular, the BEER approach can capture the sources of changes in capital accounts as well as other factors affecting the behavior of the REER. In fact, according to Clark and MacDonald (2000), exchange rate misalignments resulting from the BEER approach at any point in time can be decomposed into the effect of transitory factors, random disturbances and the extent to which the economic fundamentals are away from their sustainable values. BEER models in China have generally produced much lower estimates of the renminbi. Studies such as Wang (2004) reported that the renminbi's value to the dollar was only about 5 percent undervalued in 2003 according to the BEER approach, and Funke and Rahn (2005) estimated that the renminbi was undervalued by about 3 percent at the end of 2002. A problem with some BEER estimates, according to Cline and Williamson (2007, p.6), "is that they are calculated from a regression for a single country rather than from crosscountry experience. Such studies are surely incapable of examining whether a country's policy intervention is or is not making the country over- or undervalued." The third yet the most widely employed approach is the FEER, or the macroeconomic balance concept of equilibrium (Das, 2009), introduced into academic analysis by John Williamson in 1983. The FEER, which is expected to simultaneously achieve internal and external balance-that is, output growth at its potential level and a sustainable current account position, is the most important and relevant approach to date for economists and policymakers to compute the degree of renminbi undervaluation given 17 China's extraordinarily large current account surplus in recent years. It, expounds Das (2009), is a "rational approach" that tries to answer the question of what level of real effective, and therefore trade-weighted, exchange rate would generate a current account surplus or deficit equal to the underlying capital flows over the business cycle, assuming that the economy is pursing internal balance, which implies full non-inflationary employment. Methodologically, the FEER is the most preferred approach by economists and policymakers alike. This, according to Cline and Williamson (2007, p.4), is "because the necessary assumption of average equilibrium over the estimation period makes even the internationally-based BEER approach less reliable." Furthermore, because of its underlying fragility and likely bias in Chinese price comparison estimates, the estimates arrived at by the PPP approach are also considered to be unreliable (Cline & Williamson, 2007). We will thus discuss the FEER approach in more detail. One of the studies in the FEER school is by Vanessa Rossi (2005) who estimated that the exchange rate of the renminbi was close to equilibrium in 2000-2001. Projecting from these results, Rossi (2005) predicted that in 2010 the undervaluation of the renminbi against the U.S. dollar would be in the range of 5.5-7 percent. Also using the FEER model, Cline (2007) estimated the needed remaining appreciation of the renminbi to be in a range of 11 to 18 percent from its 2006 level in real effective terms and 34 to 39 percent against the dollar. Why are there large variations in estimates arrived at based on the FEER methodology alone? According to Cline and Williamson (2007), the major source of discrepancies among the FEER estimates is the studies' assumptions about how much of China's current account surplus is strictly cyclical and transitory, thereby how large a 18 change in the current account of the balance of payments should be targeted. After that come different assumptions about the price elasticities of demand, including assumptions about the import content of exports, a step that turns out to be critical for calculating how much the exchange rate would need to move to close the gap between the cyclically adjusted actual and target current account balances. On the former issue, the biggest surplus reduction target-which is rationalized by China's high saving propensity-is one of Tao Wang (2004)'s estimates. Wang (2004) argues that it is in China's national interest to save in excess of the level of investment that is efficient at the world interest rate and export the resulting savings as a current account surplus. In other words, China should aim for a larger current account surplus because it has a high saving rate. However, as Cline and Williamson (2007) point out, in Wang (2004)'s exercises phenomena such as China's high saving rate are not calculated to maximize social welfare of the Chinese citizens, since there are still about a hundred million social underclass in China who save a large portion of their incomes partly because much of the saving is corporate and is not their decision at all, and partly because they are afraid of the future due to the lack of a social safety net. If one holds such a view, then a current account not enormously different from balance-similar to the objectives of most of the FEER exercises-seems to be a more natural and reasonable target. Consequently, Cline and Williamson (2007) consider the Wang (2004) calculations-which estimate China's cyclically adjusted current account surplus to be around 2 percent of GOPseriously understated. Excluding these estimates, the average for the FEER estimates summarized by Cline and Williamson (2007) is a needed renminbi appreciation of 27 19 percent in real effective terms and 36 percent in the renminbi-U.S. dollar bilateral exchange rate. On the latter issue, one study that investigates the impact of variations in trade elasticities is that of Steven Dunaway, Lamin Leigh, and Xiangming Li (2006). Their estimates of the impact of increased export and import elasticities from 1 to 1.5 are interdependent with those of the current account adjustment to be accomplished: If this is only 1 percent of GDP, lower elasticities would increase the alleged renminbi undervaluation by about 4 percent, whereas with a gap of 3 percent of GDP, the impact on the undervaluation would be about 13 percent (Cline & Williamson, 2007). The difference is substantial. However, as Cline and Williamson (2007) point out, even after accounting for the relatively large share of imported intermediates used to produce exports, China's current account balance should be expected to show relatively high response to the renminbi's REER in light of its large share of trade in GDP. So far we have seen that, despite enormous efforts, different econometric exercises based on different measures have come up with extensively varying estimates of the extent of undervaluation of the renminbi- ranging from 0 to close to 50 percent. Nevertheless, the average estimates of 18 studies summarized by Cline and Williamson (2007) indicate substantial undervaluation of the renminbi. "The simple average of the 14 estimates of the correction needed in the real effective exchange rate [of the renminbi] is a 19 percent appreciation; the corresponding simple average of the 16 estimates of the bilateral rate against the U.S. dollar is an appreciation of 40 percentS" (Cline & Williamson, 2007, p.131- s "The extreme Big Mac estimate of 138 percent needed appreciation is omitted from this average because the 'simple' PPP approach is widely regarded as inappropriate" (Cline & Williamson, 2007, p.132). 20 132). The 2006 Article IV consultation report of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) (IMF, 2006) also took this position. For example, Dominique Strauss-Kahn, the managing director of the IMF, took a swipe at the renminbi in early 2009 and declared it "significantly undervalued," emphasizing the official position of the IMF (Das, 2008). CHAPTER 4- CHINA'S EXTRAORDINARILY LARGE CURRENT ACCOUNT SURPLUS AND ITS DETERMINANTS 4.1 The Upsurge in China's Current Account Surplus in Recent Years Politicians in the United States and Western Europe often criticize China's rigid exchange rate regime. Their real concern, however, is probably not China's exchange rate policy per se, but its large and growing current account surplus-the broadest measure of net export. It was argued that, by artificially depressing the value of the renminbi, China took jobs away from its trading partners. It was also argued that the resulting global imbalances were a cause of the recent global financial crisis. Despite the fact that China's current account surplus moderated slightly in 2008 and 2009 following the global financial crisis 6 -as its external demand was seriously dampened, the country continues to display the world's largest current account surplus in absolute dollar terms (Krugman, 2010). According to Yiping Huang and Kunyu Tao (2010), the rapid expansion of China's current account surplus is, in fact, a relatively recent phenomenon with the sharpest rise occurring after 2004. Within three years, the surplus jumped from USD$68.7 billion (3.6 percent of GDP) in 2004 to its recent peak ofUSD$371.8 billion (10.8 percent ofGDP) in 2007. Bottom line is that a surplus of this magnitude relative to GOP is "unprecedented for a country of 6 According to China's State Administration of Foreign Exchange, the country's current account surplus accounted for 9.9 percent ofGDP in 2008, compared with 5.8 percent in 2009. 21 China's size and stage of development" (McGregor, 2007, p.1). Figure 4.1 plots China's current account position as percent of GOP for the period 1982 to 2008. Figure 4.1 Ch ina "s Current Account Posit ion (% GDP), 1985 - 2009 12 10 8 6 4 : 2 -4 ••... ••• _.........1. ' ~ -6 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 99 01 03 OS 07 09 Sou rce : CEI C Da ra Compan y . How does one account for an almost tripling of the current account surplus as a share of the Chinese GOP, from 3.6 percent in 2004 to close to 11 percent in 2007? What is the root cause of the problem? According to Huang and Tao (2010), there is a long list of competing explanations that may be helpful for understanding China's growing external imbalance problem. These explanations may be broadly grouped into four categories: (1) capital-intensive, industry-led growth with high domestic savings and investment; (2) total factor productivity improvements; (3) factor market distortions; and (4) exchange rate distortion and policies supporting export growth. It should be noted that these explanations are not necessarily mutually exclusive. For instance, the perceived exchange rate distortion might be applied as a part of the general policies supporting export growth (Corden, 2009). The upshot is that China's growing current account surplus is a by-product of the distinct features of China's pattern of growth over the past decades and a variety of 22 policies that are behind it, including, of course-perhaps crucially-its exchange rate policy. 4.2 Capital-Intensive, Industry-Led Growth with High Domestic Savings and Investment? We will now analysing each explanation in turn. First, since the current account surplus is, by definition, the surplus of savings over investment, some economists 8 sought to explain China's large current account surplus by examining the structural factors behind its saving and investment behavior. They argue that China's traditionally high household saving rates have risen further in recent years due to the increasing need to provide for healthcare, basic education, employment insurance and pension, given the lack of sufficient public provision of these services for the bulk of the population resulting from the restructuring of state-owned enterprises starting in the mid-1990s. In addition, investment rose with savings, but less rapidly. For example, from 2000 to 2006, saving outpaced investment even as the investment to GOP ratio increased by 10 percentage points during that period (He & Kuijs, 2007). Due in part to the widening of the domestic savingsinvestment gap during this period, China's external imbalance has thus boomed-as reflected in the sharp rise of current account surplus from 1. 7 percent of GOP in 2000 to an estimated 9 percent of GOP in 2006 (He & Kuijs, 2007). It is further argued that the increasing share of household savings in GOP has been matched by a rapid decrease in that of consumption. Although domestic consumption has grown rapidly in China for many years, it has lagged behind the overall growth rate of the economy. 7 According to Jianwu He and Louis Kuijs (2007), FDI has played an important role in China's development, in particular in transferring foreign technology. However, at 3-4 percent of GOP, FDI has not been a key source of financing. Indeed, as in most countries, domestic saving has been the key source of financing. 8 For example, Feenstra, Hai, Woo and Yao (1999) 23 However, contrary to popular thinking, household savings has not been the main driving force behind the impressive increase in China's domestic savings in recent years. According to Huang and Tao (2010), Chinese household savings as a share of GDP have, in fact, been very stable over the past decade, fluctuating slightly around 20 percent. This rate is certainly high compared to those in the OECD countries, but no higher than that of other rapidly growing East Asian ones (Huang & Tao, 2010). In fact, owing partially to low wages 9 and absence of payments of taxes or dividends to the government, much of China's high savings is done by corporations whose profits and thus savings have been experiencing a persistent increase in recent years (Carden, 2009). Corporate savings in China, according to the Bank of China governor Zhou Xiaochuan, were about 22.9 percent of GDP in 2007, roughly doubling their share in 1992 (Zhou, 2009). Thus, rising corporate savings has probably been the key factor of China's large and growing current account surplus in recent years. Zhou (2009) also suggested that, given its unique income distribution pattern, China should increase the investment rate, in addition to lowering the saving rate, in order to reduce its current account surplus. The only problem, however, is that China's investment has already risen very rapidly in recent years, both in terms of level and as a share of GDP. 1o According to Huang and Tao (2010), investment has in fact become the single most important driver of China's overall growth, accounting for almost 50 percent of real GDP growth in 2010. Consequently, China probably has limited room now to further raise the investment rate. 9 Notwithstanding reported increases in average urban wages, unskilled worker wages have not increased much because of continuous massive labor inflows from the rural economy to urban centers (Corden, 2009). 1°From around 35 percent in 1995 to 44 percent in 2006-a record high by regional standards and a level comparable to that in several other East Asian economies prior to the 1997-98 crisis (Cappiello & Ferrucci, 2008). 24 As Cappiello and Ferrucci (2008) point out, high investment shares of GOP are not uncommon for catching-up economies like China that need comparatively faster capital accumulation to keep the capital stock constant as a share of GOP. In principle, rapid investment growth may result from a rational response by the corporate sector to expectations of future demand growth in sectors that are doing well at present. By the same token, since industry is more capital intensive than other sectors, it requires a lot of investment both to offset depreciation and to expand capacity (He & Kuijs, 2007). As corporate profitability has remained broadly sound in China over the past few years, much of the country's industrial investment can be financed through retained earnings of profitable firms (which are counted as corporate savings). Another part of the correlation between investment and industry runs via government investment. According to Jianwu He and Louis Kuijs (2007, p.7), "In fast industrializing countries like China, heavy investment in infrastructure supports industrialization ... The infrastructure pays off in terms of more growth and, indirectly, more government revenues." That is why the high government investment in infrastructure will continue to be part of the pattern of growth in China. Furthermore, according to Prasad (2007), growth accounting analyses suggest that investment in physical capital has been a major contributor to China's growth during the past decade, in some recent years accounting for nearly two-thirds of nominal GOP growth. Gross fixed capital formation in factories, buildings, infrastructure, etc. has, in fact, always been high in China, but it increased even further from 35 percent of GOP in 2000 to an estimated 45 percent of GOP in 2006 (Prasad, 2007). This was combined with a rise in gross domestic savings from 37 percent of GOP in 2000 to an estimated 51 percent in 2006-one of the highest shares among economies of comparable size and level of 25 development, according to He and Kuijs (2007). Private consumption, by contrast, has made a much smaller contribution to China's growth during the same period. Thus, one distinct feature of China's growth pattern is that it is increasingly capital-intensive and industry-led, with high and increasing domestic savings and investment. Such growth pattern has certainly served the Chinese economy well in many respects. But, as Prasad (2007) points out, one consequence of this investment-heavy expansion has been relatively slow employment growth. 11 Moreover, "[w]hile factor accumulation is a time-honored path to higher growth for many developing countries, whether such a high level of savings intermediated mainly through an inefficient banking system can produce long-lasting welfare gains is dubious" (Prasad & Rajan, 2006, p.6). 4.3 Total Factor Productivity Improvements Another important explanation for the sharp rise in the current account surplus in recent years is that the Chinese economy underwent a strong, positive productivity shock which made Chinese exports far more competitive in international markets than they have ever been. According to Bert Hofman and Louis Kuijs (2007), an important feature of China's growth is that much of the GOP growth has come from rapid growth of industrial production 12 -much of it in the form of higher labor productivity. To a large extent, this is due to an earlier investment boom in physical capital and hence, increased capital-labor ratio. For example, "[i]n recent years the contribution of capital accumulation to labor productivity growth increased from 3.3 out of 7 percent per year in 1978-1993 to 5.3 out of 8.4 percent in 1993-2005, a very high figure compared with other countries" (He & Kuijs, 11 For example, from 2000 to 2005, growth of total non-agricultural employment averaged only 3 percent per annum compared with average non-agricultural GOP growth of about 9.5 percent (Prasad, 2008). 12 "In 2003-06, industry contributed 60 percent of total GOP growth in China, compared with 6 percent by agriculture and 34 percent by the services sector" (Hofman & Kuijs, 2007). 26 2007, p.3). Thus, contrary to popular thinking, total factor productivity has not been low in China, and high capital accumulation explains the bulk of the difference in labor productivity growth between China and other countries or regions. As Goldstein and Lardy (2008, p.12) points out, "Despite a 9 percent appreciation of the renminbi vis-a-vis the US dollar between June 2005 and August 2007, the price of Chinese goods imported into the United States was basically unchanged." 13 Since profit margins in China's export industry have increased (World Bank, 2007) rather than decreased, "[the] most likely explanation is that productivity growth in those industries exporting to the United States was sufficiently large that firms could more than absorb the adverse effect of the rising value of the renminbi on their earnings" (Goldstein & Lardy, 2008, p.23). Goldstein and Lardy (2008) continue to argue that the combination of a nominal appreciation of the renminbi vis-a-vis the U.S. dollar of about 9 percent and unchanged price of Chinese imports in the United States suggest that total factor productivity growth in China's export industries was about 9 percent between June 2005 and August 2007. Gang Fan, another economist with CASS, is one of many China experts who express support for Goldstein and Lardy's "hidden productivity thesis." Specifically, Fan (2007) points out that rapid productivity growth helps explain why profitability in Chinese corporations has recently been high, and why import substitution has been a prominent feature of China's recent net export surge. Thus, total factor productivity improvements in China's export industry are a convincing explanation for China's rising current account surplus in recent years. According to Goldstein and Lardy (2008, p.l2), "Prices of Chinese imports in August 2007 were 0.2 percent less than in June 2005. These estimates are not based on unit values of imports but take into account the changing composition and quality of imported goods." 13 27 4.4 Factor Market Distortions Yet another explanation about China's growing current account surplus is factor market distortions-which are also considered to be part of the Chinese government's broad policy measures to support its export-led growth model. The hypothesis is that during China's economic reform period, while the government focused on reform of the product markets, including abandoning policy interventions in domestic markets and liberalizing trade, it has, in contrast, adopted measures distorting prices of almost all factors including labor, land, energy and the natural environment in order to achieve rapid export growth. These factor market distortions have indeed exerted more upward pressures on China's already large current account surplus by lifting producers' profitability, investors' returns, and hence the international competitiveness of Chinese exports to even higher levels. According to Huang and Tao (2010), estimated factor market distortions, in fact, provide "good fits" of China's external sector surplus which rose after 2004 but peaked in 2006 at 12.2 percent ofGDP. a) Distortions in the Labor Market China's labor market has become highly distorted over the past decade or so. China is well-known for its abundant and cheap labor. This was a key factor behind China's success in labor-intensive manufacturing exports. According to Huang and Tao (2010), labor costs in China may be distorted for two interrelated reasons: segmentation of rural and urban labor markets and under development of social welfare systems. Labor market segmentation in China was largely a result of the household registration system (HRS) introduced in the pre-reform era. Although the HRS has not prevented much migration in China recently, evidenced by the largest migration in human history with nearly 150 28 million people on the move by early 2011 (National Bureau of Statistics, 2011), it conditions the terms on which migrant workers from rural areas have been able to obtain work and basic social services in urban areas, and thus erects important barriers for labor mobility in China. According to James Lee (2009, p.1), more than half of China's population lives in rural areas, and "as a legacy of past economic and pension policies, there is great disparity in both economic development and pension coverage between the urban and rural populations." While the urban population is generally better covered, the rural populations sit outside the scope of any pension coverage. Indeed the pension system and reform process in China have thus far largely ignored the rural sector. According to the World Bank (2009), China's pension system covered just 15 percent of the population as of March 2008. Moreover, "alongside the transition from collectivized agriculture, households in rural China also faced increasing integration with the broader Chinese economy, as well as international markets" (Benjamin et al., 2005, p.9). The HRS which limited the movement of people out of agriculture and the rural areas where productivity and income are much lower 14 has also generated changing terms of trade between agricultural and nonagricultural products over the period of the reform, especially in the latter half of the 1990s. As a result, agricultural prices in China declined in relation to non-agricultural prices (He & Kuijs, 2007). This not only reduces production costs in urban manufacturing industries by lowering both input and labor costs-which further improves exporters' profitability and accentuates China's already large external surplus, it is also an important 14 According to He and Kuijs (2007), productivity in agriculture is about 1/61h of that in the rest of the Chinese economy, compared to a global average ratio of 1/3. 29 reason behind the increase in rural-urban income inequality as measured by the Gini coefficient. Furthermore, during the last decade and a half, pushed by insufficient employment opportunities in rural areas and their abundant labor resources, and pulled by the fastgrowing manufacturing industries and the relatively high standard of living in urban areas, China has witnessed a domestic migration of workers from rural to urban areas on an unprecedented scale. This has resulted in the emergence of a large urban "underclass" who, lacking local or urban household registration, cannot access any of the basic social welfare benefits urban residents are entitled to, such as medical insurance, pension coverage, unemployment support and compulsory 9-year basic education, even if they have been working in cities for years. On the one hand, the large increase in the number of noncontract based, migrant workers in China's urban labor market has undoubtedly facilitated the efficient allocation of labor in accordance with market demand and supply; on the other hand, it poses a serious challenge for the development and enforcement of regulations that can offer adequate protection to those workers who now face new forms of social insecurity. According to Huang and Tao (2010, p.15), "Should urban employers make social welfare contributions for their migrant workers, their payrolls could rise by about 35 to 50 percent, which includes contribution to pension (20 percent of payroll), medical insurance (6 percent), unemployment benefit (2 percent), working injury insurance (1 percent), maternity benefits (0.8 percent) and housing entitlement (5 -10 percent)." Thus, social welfare contribution is the most important area of distortion or underpay in China's labor market. b) Distortions in the Markets for Land, Energy, and Primary Commodities 30 Over the past decade or so, also due in part to the Chinese government's deliberate policy measures to support export-led growth, the markets for land, energy, and primary commodities have also become highly distorted. These distortions which have put increasing strains on the environment, generally push factor prices and, therefore, production costs below levels otherwise would be in market environment. First, according to Huang and Tao (2010, p.16), "land [in China] is owned by the state in the cities and by the collectives in the countryside." However, since the start of the economic reform, especially over the past 20 years or so, local governments have been selling user rights of land to private investors and property developers on an unprecedented scale. According to official (National Bureau of Statistics of China) Chinese data, investment by the private sector in fixed assets such as factory buildings and machinery grew nearly threefold between 2000 and 2005. In addition, the private share of total fixed-assets investment which includes investments by collective enterprises (many of which are private) has risen from 42 percent to 60 percent during the same period (The Economist, 2007b ). However, since for a long time there had not been any market mechanism for determining land prices for industrial use in China, they were often set by the local governments at artificially low levels through under-the -table negotiations in order to attract investment and promote growth. Local governments sometimes even compete with each other in offering preferential policies to attract investment. For example, "[i]n recent years, the average fees collected from negotiated granting of land use rights were only about 16 percent of those collected through auctions" (Huang and Tao, 2010, p.16). Furthermore, according to The Economist (2007b), since most of the land appropriated for housing and factory construction has been farmland in rural areas, it has 31 rendered millions of farmers landless. In fact, many of the land owners in China have been given little or no compensation for their land loss. This probably explains why property and land disputes have become a leading cause of social unrest in China in recent years (The Economist, 2007b). Next, because China's export-led growth has been particularly intensive in energy, primary commodities, and other natural resources, its overall reliance on these inputs is high. For example, according to He and Kuijs (2007), in 2007 China used 4.5 times as much energy per US dollar of output as the United States (at market exchange rates), and 7.5 times as much as in Japan. Also in 2007, China consumed more than 30 percent of the world total consumption of coal, steel, tin and cement (Streifel, 2007). However, as Huang and Tao (2010) expound, when international prices of key energy products such as oil, gas, and coal moved violently upward, the Chinese government were reluctant to follow for fear of disrupting economic growth. For instance, when international crude oil prices reached their recent peak, at close to $150 per barrel in 2008, the equivalent domestic prices were only around $80 per barrel in China (Huang & Tao, 2010). With the acceleration of industry growth and as the markets for land, energy, and primary commodities become increasingly distorted, emission and pollution are another problem facing China today. According to He and Kuijs (2007), after a long period of declining nitrous oxide (NOx) and sulphur dioxide (S02) emission, they rose again since 2003. "With 16 of the 20 cities with the worst air pollution in the world are in China, the country has become the largest source of S02 emission in the world and may soon become the largest emitter of carbon dioxide (C02); some say the country already is" (He & Kuijs, 2007, p.10). Today, poor air quality is still a very visible issue in China, and costly, especially in large cities. A 32 recent study done by the World Bank (2007) estimates that the health costs of air pollution amounted to about 3.8 percent of the Chinese GOP in 2007. In addition, according to Hofman and Kuijs (2007), one-third of China's landmass regularly experiences acid rain, causing an estimated environmental damage of some $13 billion U.S. dollar, or 1 percent of China's (2003) GOP per year. "Since producers do not always fully compensate their damages to the environment, it reduces the short-term production costs, at the expense of long-term development of the whole economy and society" (Huang & Tao, 2010, p.17). Thus, despite China's remarkable economic progress, it still has a long way to go to make its growth more environmentally sustainable. 4.5 Exchange Rate Distortion and Policies Promoting Export Growths Finally, we move to the central question and the most reasonable explanation for the surge in China's current account surplus in recent years, at least on the surface. In the view that exchange rate distortion and policies supporting export have played a crucial role in boosting China's current account surplus, an increasingly undervalued renminbi under China's current rigid exchange rate regime raises the country's export and depresses its imports, and thus inflates its current account surplus. The common argument, which has been most frequently referenced in public debate about China's external imbalances, is that if the renminbi were allowed to float, it would appreciate substantially more, and this would reduce China's high current account surplus. According to Goldstein (2007), despite an appreciation of the renminbi against the U.S. dollar since June 2005, the REER of the renminbi-widely regarded as a more comprehensive and superior measure of the overall competitiveness of Chinese exportshad actually depreciated since the dollar peak in February 2002. The depreciation ranges 33 from 2 to 11 percent, depending on the measure chosen (Goldstein, 2007). Figure 4.2 displays China's REER from 1994Q1 to 2008Q2. According to Lardy (2007), usually, external payment adjustments call for appreciation of the REERs of the domestic currencies, that is, for declines in external competitiveness in countries with large current account or trade surpluses. In the case of China, however, the REER of the renminbi has moved in a direction opposite to what is needed. Lardy (2007) continues to argue that even indicators of the REER understate the improvement in China's competitive position in global trade because "the price indices used to construct them include some non-tradable goods and hence do not give adequate weight to rapid productivity growth in China's export industries. Figure 4.2 China 's Real Effective Exchange Rate, 1994Ql-2008Q2 110 g 100 II 0 0 0 ~ f? .8 90 E :::1 z " .:"' "0 80 70 oeffiooooooooooooosaooosooc;aooooooosooc;ooaooooc;aooooooooooc; ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ ~~~~ ~~ Time Period So urce: Internation al Monetary Fund (2008), IM F (Internat ional Fi nanc ial Stat isti cs, IFS) Goldstein and Lardy (2006) applied the "underlying balance" approach to evaluate the misalignment of the renminbi. As discussed in Chapter 3, the essence of their approach was to calculate the needed adjustments in the renminbi's REER in order to retain a 34 "normal" current account balance. They concluded that resisting underlying pressures for REER appreciation-coming partially from China's high productivity growth in its traded goods sector relative to that of its trading partners-had contributed to growing trade surplus and, at least in some years, had fed very large portfolio capital inflows, which appeared motivated by an expectation of renminbi appreciation. Furthermore, applying data for the period of 1994 to 2003, Xiangqian Lu and Guoqiang Dai (2005) examined the long-run relationship between China's international trade and the renminbi's REER. Results of their co-integrated vector auto regression (VAR) model suggested that the renminbi's REER had significant impacts on China's exports and imports. These results confirm the fact that the renminbi's REER has indeed been an important determinant of China's anomalous current account imbalance in recent years (Huang & Tao, 2010). Nevertheless, it is important to point out that the maintenance of a rigid exchange rate regime since at least the mid-1990s is only part of China's export-led growth strategy, and that by the same token, the country's large external surplus is a by-product of policies supporting export growth. Yu Yongding, another prominent economist with CASS, identified China's exportpromotion policy, which includes the so-called "self-balancing" regulation, exchange rate policy and tax rebate, as another contributing factor to China's current account surplus in recent years. According to Yu (2007), the Chinese authorities demanded foreign investors to guarantee the "self-balancing" of foreign exchange for important investment projects. In other words, FDI in China must be export-oriented. This is evidenced by the fact that all the multinational corporations are now in China, and all of them aim to export to the international market. In 2009, for example, 60 percent of China's export is actually from 35 multinational corporations, either joint ventures or foreign investment companies (Corden, 2009). This, as concurred by Corden (2009), is another fundamental reason for China's growing current account surplus in recent years. Yet there have also been other factors. As is pointed out by Prema-chandra Athukorala (2009), China's accession into the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001 significantly improved the attractiveness of its domestic investment climate for exportoriented production. Consequently, the process of relocation to China, from Japan, Taiwai and Korea especially, of final assembly activities of information and communication technology products accelerated. In addition, according to Corden (2009), WTO accession contributed significantly to improve investor confidence in the Chinese economy, and this might also be regarded as a productivity improvement in the export sector. Although this showed up in China's current account balance with a time lag (Corden, 2009), the overall picture is that China's export growth intensified following its WTO accession. The Chinese authorities' policy bias in favor of strong, export-led growth is well known. In fact, a significant part of China's growth stems from increasing production of manufactured goods. According to Hofman and Kuijs (2007), while aggregate demand and supply in China's economy are growing broadly in line with each other, a large share of the demand is coming from abroad, instead of Chinese households and businesses. Under the investment-heavy, export-oriented pattern of growth, and with surplus labor in agriculture keeping wage growth below productivity gains, production in China increasingly outstrips domestic demand (Hofman & Kuijs, 2007). Thus, from an external perspective, accelerating manufacturing production means continued strong export expansion. 36 Also according to Huang and Tao (2010), over the past few years China has chosen to boost manufacturing production at whatever costs. One prosaic explanation is that China still has huge surplus labor in the countryside, and at the same time does not have welldeveloped social welfare system. Thus, a key challenge facing the government is job creation. The widely accepted 8 percent growth target, for instance, was formulated based on employment pressure (Huang & Tao, 2010). Another policy orientation, according to Huang and Tao (2010), is to maintain stability on the domestic and external fronts while opening up to trade and financial flows, especially after the Asian financial crisis in 199798. In this context, the buildup of foreign exchange reserves resulting from these policies may serve as a form of self-insurance against vulnerabilities arising from the country's weak baking system. However, as Eswar Prasad and Raghuram Rajan (2006, p.S) point out, there comes a point when the policy distortions-especially exchange rate distortionneeded to maintain this approach "could generate imbalances, impose potentially large welfare costs, and themselves become a source of instability." In fact, at least since 2006 China's foreign exchange reserves have been well above the level that seemed to be required (Carden, 2009). Consequently, the Chinese authorities have made improving quality of growth a top policy priority (see, for example, Wen 2006). Albeit exchange rate policy-as reflected in the reluctance to let the renminbi appreciate in line with China's development progress-has just been one part of the story, it can and does affect the country's external surplus. Does it really matter anyway? As Jonathan Anderson (2008, p.66) points out, "Whatever the driving force, the fact that China has seen a high and sharply rising current account surplus over the past few years clearly means that the renminbi is undervalued in a near-term, workaday sense." Consequently, if the 37 Chinese authorities were really hoping to reduce the country's external surplus, a more flexible exchange rate regime that would bring about significant real appreciation of the renminbi could definitely be part of the policy prescription. CHAPTER 5- CONUNDRUMS FACING THE CHINESE AUTHORITIES UNDER THE CURRENT EXCHANGE RATE REGIME 5.1 Monetary Policy Independence As China undergoes market reforms and integrates into the world economy, monetary policy is a crucial means through which the Chinese authorities manage the country's complex and rapidly changing economic situation. Because monetary policy carries with it system-wide implications for the Chinese economy, even at the microeconomic level, the flexibility and effectiveness of monetary policy are of particular importance under China's unique circumstances. More specifically, according to the Deputy Governor of the PBOC Hu Xiaolian, "[m]onetary policy in China helps achieve various objectives, including managing inflation, supporting growth, promoting a balanced BOP account, boosting employment and facilitating financial reform" (Hu, 2010, p.1). However, over the last decade or so, China's rigid exchange rate regime has imposed a substantial constraint on the conduct of its monetary policy and the impact is likely to continue (Goldstein & Lardy, 2006; Lardy, 2006; Prasad et al., 2005). According to Hu (2010), prior to 1993, China ran surpluses in the current account and in the capital account-the two principal divisions of the balance of payments (BOP)on an alternate basis. The situation changed in 1994 when China began to run "twin surpluses" of its BOP (a large and growing current account surplus compounded by a surplus in the capital account), and intensified following China's accession to the WTO in 2001. For example, China recorded a current account surplus of USD$250 billion in 2006 38 (9.3 percent of GOP), on top of which net financial inflows 15 contributed to increase further the country's overall BOP surplus (Cappiello & Ferrucci, 2008). Normally, a large expansion of BOP surplus would lead to appreciation pressures on the domestic currency, which in turn would lead to deterioration in the country's competitive position in international trade. This can happen even with little flexibility in its exchange rate regime. However, resisting pressures for renminbi appreciation, the PBOC intervenes massively in the foreign exchange market by purchasing a large amount of foreign exchange-to the tune of about US0$20 billion a month in 2006 and US0$45 billion a month in the first quarter of 2007 (Goldstein, 2007). According to Goldstein (2007, p.7), in each of the past three years from 2007, "China's exchange market intervention has amounted to roughly 10 percent of its GOP-a truly extraordinary amount." The renminbi equivalent of foreign exchange purchases has in turn fueled a surge in the supply of base money, and generates a "liquidity overhang" in the banking and financial system. Such liquidity overhang has in turn led to inflation in the Chinese economy. For example, the inflation rate in China was last reported at 5.3 percent in April 2011, compared to an average of 4.25 percent over the 1994-2010 period (PBOC, 2011). 16 Moreover, in a recent Chinese article, CASS economist Qiyuan Xu (2010) points out that the official CPI data has been "systematically under-reported by the government" since his research found that over 7 percent of price increases in the Chinese economy could not be explained by the subcategories and their assigned weight for the past 5 years or so. 15 According to Cappiello and Ferrucci (2008), net FDI inflows in China averaged nearly 5 percent of GOP annually in the five years prior to the Asian financial crisis. They have fallen since then, but were still US0$61 billion in 2006 (2.3 percent of GOP). Other capital flows-probably mostly speculative in nature-grew significantly in 2004 (to US0$91 billion) but were negative in the following two years. 16 Source: PBOC Statistics for 2011 and author's own calculations. 39 Under the current situation, relatively high domestic interest rates would be needed to cool down China's "overheated" economy and to rein in inflation. However, the paradox is that higher domestic interest rates in relation to foreign rates would attract higher levels of speculative capital inflows, which would put even higher upward pressures on the renminbi exchange rate. Furthermore, as Goldstein and Lardy (2009) point out, "[c]apital controls, in theory, could prevent large inflows [of international capital] when domestic interest rates are higher than foreign rates, but in practice it is difficult to maintain effective controls over time, particularly in an economy [like China] that is very open to trade." In fact, as Robert Mundell (2004) points out, the serious challenges faced by China's monetary policies are those implied by the "impossible trinity" hypothesis which postulates that in an integrated world economy, it is impossible for a country to achieve simultaneously exchange rate stability, monetary independence, and free international movement of capital. So far, however, it appears that it has been possible for the Chinese authorities to keep the renminbi exchange rate relatively stable without overriding domestic monetary policy. This, according to Cappiello and Ferrucci (2008), is achieved by "imposing tight controls on the capital account and by maintaining close restrictions on the cross-border movement of capital... [which] has allowed a certain degree of monetary autonomy to be retained through the use of administrative measure, such as increase in the reserve requirement ratio on bank deposits and the so-called 'window guidance' policy, which aims to control the growth of domestic credit to certain sectors" (Cappiello & Ferrucci, 2008, p.15). For example, the compulsory reserve requirement ratio on bank deposits increased 40 from 7.5 percent in July 2005 to 19.5 percent in May 2011 (PBOC, 2011). Nevertheless, as Hu (2010) points out, the root cause of China's liquidity problem, i.e., the rapid expansion of renminbi supply as a result of foreign exchange purchases has not been solved. Thus, if China wants to ensure price stability and, by doing so, to promote higher-quality economic growth, it must face a trade-off between exchange rate stability and interest rate liberalization, which is a key condition for the development of an independent and effective monetary policy. 5.2 China's Large Hoarding of Foreign Exchange Reserves Also as a net result of China's current account surplus, its massive open-market foreign exchange interventions, as well as capital inflows responding to the incentives created by its rigid exchange rate policy, the PBOC has accumulated an extraordinarily large hoarding of foreign exchange reserve (now passed USD$3 trillion) with U.S. dollars making up a large part of the total. Given that China trades mostly with the United States, the choice of the U.S. dollar as the primary reserve currency is not surprising. However, the resultant rapid accumulation of U.S. dollar-denominated foreign assets-predominately in the form of the U.S. Treasury bills (T -bills )-entail some large risks and costs, and therefore has not been in the long-term interest of China. As Carden (2007) explains, China's ownership of vast amounts of U.S. T-bills-which are regarded as the least risky investment available on the planet-tends to yield a very low rate of return and is very likely to lose real value relative to the prices of non-dollar goods in the face of U.S. dollar depreciation. The Chinese authorities seem to be well aware of this problem, but the low yield does not seem to bother them much. They are, apparently, worried more about the fact that 41 around 70 percent of their foreign assets are dollar-denominated, so any sharp decline in the value of the U.S. dollar would mean huge capital losses on the balance sheet of the Chinese monetary authority (Krugman, 2009). "Suppose that the eventual dollar decline andre-equilibration of the renminbi result in a 20 percent capital loss for China. This would amount to USD$400 billion or roughly 10 percent of the Chinese GOP," according to economist Arvind Subramanian (2009). In fact, the threat of dollar deprecation has become more immediate due to the continuous deterioration in the fiscal balance of the U.S. economy. Certainly, China would like to tear itself away from the U.S. Treasury market, but as one might expect, "[a] precipitous action by China to shift aggressively out of U.S. dollardenominated instruments, or even an announcement of such an intention, could act as a trigger that nervous market sentiments coalesce around, leading to a sharp fall in bond prices and the value of the U.S. dollar" (Prasad, 2010). As a result, the Chinese authorities have shown few signs of attempting to weaken the dollar. The reason for this seems straightforward: such a move would not be without cost for China. After all, China is the world's largest dollar investor, and no one else would have less interest in seeing the value of the U.S. currency plummet than China would. In a recent New York Times column, Paul Krugman (2009) argues that China has in fact "driven itself into a 'dollar trap', and that it can neither get itself out nor change the policies that put it in that trap in the first place."17 17 Recently, some Chinese policymakers argue that renminbi appreciation would have the same effect on the value of China's foreign exchange reserves. For example, in an article published on Caixin's Century Weekly on May 2, Anyuan Zhang, head of the fiscal and financial policy research division of the National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC)'s Institute of Economic Research, predicted that China will lose USD$578.6 billion in its foreign exchange reserves if the nominal RMB-USD bilateral exchange rate drops to 6. However, an unnamed official with China's State Administration of Foreign Exchange (SAFE) said in a statement May 6 that renminbi appreciation will not directly reduce the value of China's foreign exchange reserves. According to the statement, the real purchasing power of China's foreign exchange reserves would remain unchanged 42 5.3 Banking Sector Reforms In order to prevent the risks of hyperinflation in the domestic economy, China's central bank must conduct large-scale, open-market sterilization operations. However, such sterilization may not only run into limits quickly, it entails some costs on the domestic banking system. These costs, which are likely to increase more than proportionally as the stock of China's foreign exchange reserves rises (Cappiello & Ferrucci, 2008), may in turn hamper banking sector reforms in China. According to Cappiello and Ferrucci (2008), China's open-market sterilization operations are normally carried out through sterilization bills issued by the central bank. As a rough estimate, the PBOC currently sterilizes around half of the increase in its foreign exchange reserves, and in March 2007, the outstanding stock of sterilization debt was around 40 percent of official reserves (Cappiello & Ferrucci, 2008). However, as the total stock of sterilization bonds increases, the PBOC have to offer increasingly higher interest rates or yields to convince domestic economic agents to hold them. As Goldstein and Lardy (2009, p.28) point out, "Eventually, the interest the central bank pays on these bonds could exceed it earnings from its holdings of interest-bearing foreign currency-denominated financial assets, imposing a substantial financial constraint on sterilization operations." Equally important, such sterilization operations have also perpetuated large efficiency costs due to the provision of large amounts of low-yielding central bank bills mainly to inefficient state-owned enterprises (Dollar & Wei, 2007). According to some estimates, loans extended since 2002 represent around 57 percent of the total loan book of despite fluctuations in the renminbi exchange rate. Substantive changes would occur only when huge amounts of reserves are repatriated and converted to the renminbi, a scenario that is unlikely to happen because China faces no such pressure. 43 Chinese commercial banks (Setser, 2005). Thus, as Cappiello and Ferrucci (2008) expound, the health of China's banking system depends increasingly on the quality of the central bank loans extended during the current lending boom. If a fraction of these loans becomes non-performing, commercial banks in China could face huge capital losses. Furthermore, in order to control credit growth given the inability of the PBOC to use interest rates as a primary tool of monetary policy, the Chinese authorities have to resort to credit quotas such as required reserve ratios for individual banks as well as various types of "window guidance" on bank lending as mentioned earlier. This, however, "vitiates the process of banking reform by keeping banks' lending growth under the administrative guidance of the [PBOC] rather than letting it be guided by market signals" (Prasad, 2007, p.8). In the first quarter of 2011 alone, as inflationary pressures remain in the spotlight, the PBOC raised the ratio three times to a record high of 20 percent, based on its public statements (Back & Orlik, 2011). The upshot, according to Goldstein and Lardy (2009, p.30), is that the PBOC's need both to place large amounts of low-yielding sterilization bills with commercial banks and to repeatedly raise their requirement reserves (which likewise pay low interests) has an adverse impact on the profitability of these banks, and thus "hindering their transition to operation on a fully commercial basis." 5.4 Rebalancing of the Chinese Economy Lastly, a few statistics quickly illustrate how skewed or unbalanced China's economic structure has become in recent years. According to Simon Tilford (2009, p.1), "While the household savings rate is running at over 20 percent of income, household consumption represented just 35 percent of GOP in 2008-an exceptionally low share by any standards." This is probably a product of social and culture forces, which still 44 emphasize savings. Nevertheless, China has been able to produce much more than it consumes by exporting the difference. The surge of cheap Chinese products has definitely benefited consumers in the advanced economies-notably the United States-by boosting their disposable incomes, but, at the same time, distorted China's economic structure. For their part, the Americans have been able to live beyond their means because of the readiness of the Chinese authorities to purchase huge quantities of U.S. government debts in the form of U.S. Treasury bonds and bills. This, according to Tilford (2009), is a reversal of the norm. "Developing countries usually import capital because their domestic savings are inadequate to meet their high investment needs ... For a developing country to be lending capital to the most important developed economy in order for it to buy the developing country's goods is not something that has happened before" (Tilford, 2009, p.2). However, Tilford (2009) continues to point out that if something cannot go on forever, it will not. Countries cannot run huge deficits indefinitely-not even the U.S. The recent global financial crisis has indeed demonstrated this. In fact, the current account deficits of big consumer countries like the U.S. are narrowing, and this trend will likely to continue. U.S. households, for example, are likely to save more in the years ahead, and hence consume less. The Obama administration has recently made plain that the world can no longer rely on the U.S. acting as the "consumer of last resort." It is against this backdrop that many Chinese policymakers have started to fear that Chinese exports will never again play the same role in driving growth in the Chinese economy. Indeed, China's leadership is aware that there needs to be a rebalancing of its economy if the country is to maintain its rapid economic growth. For example, in a recent government work report to the annual parliamentary session, Chinese premier Wen Jiabao 45 said: "We should focus on restructuring the economy, and make greater effort to enhance the role of domestic demand, especially consumption, in spurring growth." The Chinese government knows that sustainable growth requires a very big shift from external to domestic demand. This, however, requires the Chinese people to produce less and to consume more of what they produce. Thus, in order to put the Chinese economy on a sound footing, China must shift towards a more consumption-based economy. A more flexible exchange rate regime while not the only answer to the imbalance problem of the Chinese economy, it is an essential part of the issue. With it, China can transition to a consumption-driven growth path at a much faster pace since a renminbi appreciation would reduce the growth of exports and increase the growth of imports, and thereby promoting a more efficient allocation of domestic resources between the tradable and non-tradable sectors. Without it, the problem cannot be resolved. As Prasad (2007, p.10) points out, "The case for a flexible exchange rate rests on a deeper set of policy priorities, with the ultimate objective being balanced and sustainable growth in the longer term." This, in fact, is very much in the interest of China's vast population. CHAPTER 6 - CONCLUDING REMARKS By reviewing the Chinese and western literature, this paper finds that the latest debates on the renminbi exchange rate regime in China mirror those in the west. Specifically, there are same rival camps both inside and outside China surrounding two key issues - first, whether the renminbi is significantly undervalued, and second, whether China would benefit from adopting a more flexible exchange rate regime. With respect to the first issue, one camp, i.e., CASS economists Ming Zhang (2010c, 2011) and Yongding Yu (2010) along with some western economists [e.g., Rossi (2005), 46 Cline and Williamson (2007), Goldstein and Lardy (2008)] support the IMF (2006)'s position that the renminbi is substantially undervalued. However, in response to accusations ofrenminbi undervaluation, the other camp which includes high-level officials in China (e.g., Wen (2006)] and some Chinese academics such as professors Yu Zhang, Haiping Qiu, and Wei ping Huang at Renmin University and professor Jiandong Ju at Tsinghua University 1B disagree with the argument that China's large and growing current account surplus proves that the renminbi is significantly undervalued. They argue that a structural reduction in the balance of payments surplus was already unfolding in China thanks to steps taken to boost domestic consumption. They also retorted that greater pressure from abroad for more rapid exchange rate reform would only slow the process down since there had not been any consensus on the degree of renminbi undervaluation (e.g., People's Daily, 13/05/2005). However, does it matter how much the renminbi is undervalued? Is the degree of undervaluation the primary focus of the current renminbi debate? The answers are no. As discussed earlier, an independent monetary policy, which is a crucial tool for improving domestic macroeconomic management and promoting stable economic growth and low inflation, "requires a flexible exchange rate, not a one-off revaluation or a sequence of revaluations" (Prasad, 2007, p.13). As Prasad (2007, p.13) explains, "A flexible exchange rate buffers some of the effects of interest rate changes, especially in offsetting the temptation for capital to flow in or out in response to such changes. A one-off revaluation can solve this problem temporarily but could create even more problems subsequently if interest rate actions in a different direction become necessary, or if investor sentiment and 18 Meetings with these Chinese Economics professors were undertaken in Beijing in November 2010. 47 the pressures for capital inflows or outflows shift." Hence, the increase of the flexibility of the renminbi exchange rate regime is more important than a mere appreciation of the renminbi, concurs CASS economists Zhang (2010b) and Yu (2010). With respect to the second issue, the commonality the two camps share is the viewpoint that a more flexible renminbi exchange rate is in China's own best interests as it can resolve many of the challenges and obstacles posed by its current tightly managed exchange rate regime that have been highlighted in the previous chapter. It would not only allow the PBOC to gain more control over China's domestic monetary conditions given its excessive accumulation of foreign exchange reserves that has accompanied the increasingly undervalued renminbi and other factors, it would also prevent further buildup of liquidity in the domestic financial system, thereby promoting banking sector reforms in China. In addition, a more flexible exchange rate regime can support China's transition to a more balanced and sustained growth path by reducing the reliance of exports and promoting domestic consumption. Hence, "[a] strong argument can be made for an early move towards greater exchange rate flexibility, irrespective of whether or not the renminbi is substantially undervalued" (Cappiello & Ferrucci, 2008, p.8). Albeit there is no real dispute between the two camps both inside and outside China that the renminbi exchange rate has to become more flexible, what can we say about the speed of the adjustment? The Chinese authorities representing one camp have repeatedly stated their resolve to move toward increased exchange rate flexibility. However, as Cappiello and Ferrucci (2008) point out, they have also expressed concerns that some conditions have to be in place to ensure a smooth transition to a more flexible renminbi exchange rate system. "In particular, a number of institutional reforms have to be 48 implemented in order to prepare the economic system to manage exchange rate risk. These include developing a proper foreign exchange market, where the central bank shifts from acting as a rate-setter to a supervisory role, and introducing more sophisticated hedging instruments. The financial and non-financial corporate sectors will also have to learn to adapt to increased foreign exchange risk" (Cappiello & Ferrucci, 2008, p.29). Thus, they argue that a sudden move toward a fully floating renminbi exchange rate regime is not advisable, and therefore should not be envisaged, in the short to medium term. The other camp [e.g., Prasad (2007), Goldstein and Lardy (2008), Yu (2010), and Zhang (2011)] disagrees, arguing that an independent monetary policy that is able to guide credit expansion through domestic interest rate adjustments is essential to encourage commercial banks to become more robust financial institutions. Consequently, it is also a key input into durable banking sector reforms in China. Nevertheless, the Chinese authorities often express concern that, given the fragility and underdevelopment of the country's financial and banking system, more exchange rate flexibility-which is the key ingredient for an independent monetary policy-could be disastrous in the event of a sharp increase in the value of the renminbi as it could destroy bank balance sheets (Prasad, 2007). However, according to Prasad (2007, p.14), "there is little evidence that Chinese banks have large exposures to foreign currency assets or external liabilities denominated in renminbi that would hurt their balance sheets greatly if the renminbi were to appreciate in the short run." In addition, according to Zhang (2010c), over the past few years, especially since the onset of the recent global financial crisis in 2008, the world's advanced economies such as the US, the EU and Japan have been experiencing relatively slow economic growth, whereas 49 newly industrialized countries (NIC) including China have been experiencing higher growth. For the advanced economies, their primary goal after the crisis is to stimulate domestic economic growth. However, due to their worsening fiscal deficit and government debt problems, there is not much leeway for further fiscal stimulus. Also against the backdrop of high unemployment, these countries have put promoting export growth at top of their priority lists. Thus, driving down the values of their currencies and pressuring the NICs to appreciate their ones have become their main strategy. As advanced economies notably the United States resort to quantitative easing policies to depreciate their currencies in an effort to promote export growth, and as NICs like China continue to interfere in the foreign exchange market to prevent their currencies from appreciating, a global currency war has thus begun (Zhang, 2010c). What are the implications of such a global currency war for China? As Zhang (2010c) expounds, the rejection by the Chinese authorities of any call for the increase in the flexibility of the renminbi exchange rate regime and thus a renminbi appreciation large enough to make a real dent in China's current account surplus may exacerbate the problem and create a lose-lose situation for China and the rest of the world-notably the advanced economies. So how then can we explain the glacial pace of exchange rate reform in China? Why are the Chinese authorities reluctant to let its exchange rate regime become much more flexible? They are, in fact, more concerned about the potential economic costs associated with greater exchange rate flexibility. Their primary concern, according to Cappiello and Ferrucci (2008), is that a much more flexible exchange rate regime under which a significant appreciation of the renminbi is likely to occur may hurt China's external competitiveness, thereby reducing export growth and weakening FDI inflows. Since export so growth has been an important engine of China's spectacular economic performance in the past decades, it is feared that a weakened export capacity may jeopardize overall growth prospects and be disastrous for employment and hence, social stability. This may be an important reason why exchange rate reform is a highly politically sensitive issue in China. A related concern is that higher renminbi exchange rate under a flexible exchange rate regime could adversely affect rural incomes in the country (Cappiello & Ferrucci, 2008). As Cappiello and Ferrucci (2008) expound, the Chinese rural sector is widely believed to be internationally uncompetitive due to the large amount of surplus labor combined with low productivity growth. Consequently, the Chinese policymakers fear that a fall in domestic prices of food imports resulting from a renminbi appreciation may have significant adverse consequences for farmers. The upshot is that although a more flexible exchange rate regime which would bring about a significant appreciation of the renminbi would be beneficial for the Chinese economy as a whole, the benefits would not be shared equally among different sectors of the economy. 51 REFERENCES Anderson, J. (2008). Renminbi Revaluation and US Dollar Depreciation. Comment on Goldstein, M., & Lardy, N. (eds)' Debating China's Exchange Rate Policy. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C., U.S. Athukorala, P. (2009). The Rise of China and East Asian Export Performance: Is the Crowding out Fear Warranted? The World Economy, 32: 234-266. Back, A., & Orlik, T. (2011). China Raises Reserve Ratio for Banks. The Wall Street journal, March 18, 2011. Batson, A. (2010). China's Current-Account Surplus Fell in 2009. The Wall Street journal, February 13, 2010. Benjamin, D., Brandt, L., Giles, J., & Wang, S. (2005). Income Inequality during China's Economic Transition. China's Economic Transition: Origins, Mechanisms, and Consequences. Cappiello, L., & Ferrucci, G. (2008). The Sustainability of China's Exchange Rate Policy and Capital Account Liberalization. European Central Bank Occasional Paper Series No. 82 (March, 2008). Clark, P., & MacDonald, R. (1999). Exchange Rates and Economic Fundamentals: A Methodological Comparison of BEERs and FEERs. In R. MacDonald and J. Stein ( eds.), Equilibrium Exchange Rates. Amsterdam: Kluwer Academic. Clark, P., & MacDonald, R. (2000). Filtering the BEER: A permanent and transitory decomposition. IMF Working Paper WP /00/144, August. Cline, W. (2007). Estimating Reference Exchange Rates. Paper presented at the workshop on policy to reduce global imbalances, sponsored by Bruegel, the Korean Institute for International Economic Policy, and the Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, February 8-9. Cline, W., & Williamson, J. (2007). Estimates of the Equilibrium Exchange Rate of the Renminbi: Is There a Consensus and, If Not, Why Not? Paper presented at the Conference on China's Exchange Rate Policy, Peterson Institute, Washington D.C., October 12, 2007. Carden, W. M. (2007). Those Current Account Imbalances: A Sceptical View. The World Economy, 30: 363-82. 52 Carden, W. M. (2009). China's Exchange Rate Policy, Its Current Account Surplus and the Global Imbalances. In Ross Garnaut, Ligang Song and Wing Thye Woo (eds.), China's New Place in a World in Crisis. ANU E-Press, Canberra, Australia, and Brookings Institution, Washington D.C., U.S. Das, D. K. (2006). The dollar correction period and the Asian currencies. Derivatives: Use, Trading and Regulations. Vol. 11(4). London. pp. 345-365. Das, D. K. (2008). Rapid growth in China and the Asian economies: Some stylized freemarket policy inferences (val. 28). London; Economic Affairs, pp. 57-67. Das, D. K. (2 009). The evolution of renminbi yuan and the protracted debate on its undervaluation: An integrated review. journal ofAsian Economics, 20:570-579. Dollar, D., & Wei, S. (2007). Das (Wasted) Kapital: Firm Ownership and Investment Efficiency in China. IMF Working Paper 07/9. Washington: International Monetary Fund. Dunaway, S., Leigh, L., & Li, X. (2006). How Robust Are Estimates of Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate for China? IMF Working Paper 06/220 (October). Washington: International Monetary Fund. Fan, G. (2007). Renminbi Revaluation and US Dollar Depreciation. Paper Presented at the Conference on China's Exchange Rate Policy held at the Peterson Institute for International Economics, October 19, 2007. Feenstra, R., Wen, H., Woo, W. T., & Yao, S. (1999). Discrepancies in International Data: an Application to China-Hong Kong Entrepot Trade. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 89, 338-343. Frankel, J., & Wei, S.J. (2007). Assessing China's Exchange Rate Regime. Paper prepared for the 44th Panel Meeting of Economic Policy, February 12, 2007. Funke, M., & Rahn, J. (2005). Just how undervalued is the Chinese renminbi? World Economy, 28(4), 465-689. Goldstein, M. (2007). A (Lack of) Progress Report on China's Exchange Rate Policies. Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper 07-5 ljune). Washington: Peterson Institute for International Economics. Goldstein, M., & Lardy, N. (2004 ). What Kind of Landing for the Chinese Economy? Policy Briefs in International Economics 04-7. Washington: Institute for International Economics. 53 Goldstein, M., & Lardy, N. (2006). China's Exchange Rate Dilemma. American Economics Review (May): 422-26. Goldstein, M., & Lardy, N. eds. (2008). Debating China's Exchange Rate Policy. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C., U.S. Goldstein, M., & Lardy, N. (2009). The Future of China's Exchange Rate Policy. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, D.C., U.S. He, J., & Kuijs, L. (2007). Rebalancing China's Economy-Modelling a Policy Package. World Bank China Research Paper No. 7. Hofman, B., & Kuijs, L. (2007). Rebalancing China's Growth. Paper Presented at the Conference on China's Exchange Rate Policy held at the Peterson Institute for International Economics, October 19, 2007. Hu, X. (2010). Exchange Rate Regime Reform and Monetary Policy Effectiveness. Article by Ms Hu Xiaolian, Deputy Governor of the People's Bank of China, Beijing, 26 July 2010. Huang, Y., & Tao, K. (2010). Causes and Remedies of China's External Imbalances. China Center for Economic Research Working Paper Series No. E2010002. Peking University. Huang, H., & Wang, S. (2004). Exchange Rate Regimes: China's Experience and Choices. China Economic Review, 15: 336-342. IMF (International Monetary Fund). (2006). People's Republic of China: 2006 Article IV Consultation. IMP Country Report 06/394 (October). Washington. IMF (International Monetary Fund). (2008). International Financial Statistics Data File. Available at http: //www.imfstatistics.org/IMF /ImfBrowser.aspx IMF (International Monetary Fund). (2011). World Economic Outlook Database: April 2011 Edition. Available at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2011/01/weodatalindex.aspx Krugman, P. (2010). Chinese New Year. New York Times (Opinion page), January 1, 2010. Lardy, N. (2002). Integrating China into the Global Economy. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institutions. Lardy, N. (2006). China: Toward a Consumption-Driven Growth Path. Policy Briefs in International Economics 06-6. Washington: Peterson Institute for International Economics. Lardy, N. (2007). China: Rebalancing Economic Growth. Available at www.chinabalancesheet.org. 54 Lee, J. (2009). Pension System Developments: China faces up to its biggest challenge. London: IPE International Publishers Limited (October). Lu, X., & Dai, G. (2005). The Influence of Fluctuation of Real RMB Exchange Rate to Chinese Import and Export: 1994-2003. Economic Research, 2005(5). McGregor, R. (2007). China's Trade Surplus Overshadows Talks. Financial Times, May 11. Mundell, R. (2004). China's Exchange Rate: The Case for the Status Quo. Paper presented at the International Monetary Fund seminar on the Foreign Exchange System, Dalian, China (May). National Bureau of Statistics, China Statistical Yearbook, various issues. People's Bank of China. (2005). Financial Stability Review, September 2005, Part II, page 17. People's Bank of China. (2008). China's Monetary Circulation Equilibrium in 2007 (January 11). Available at http://www.pbc.gov.cn People's Bank of China. (2011). Survey and Statistics. Available at http: //www.p bc.gov.cn /publish/english /9 58/index.html People's Daily (13/05/2005). China never yields to outside pressure on RMB exchange rate: Premier Wen. Available at http://english.people.eom.cn/200505116/eng20050516 185298.html Prasad, E. (2007). Monetary Policy Independence, the Currency Regime, and the Capital Account in China. Paper presented at the Conference on China's Exchange Rate Policy, Peterson Institute for International Economics, October 19, 2007. Prasad, E., & Raj an, R. (2006). Modernizing China's Growth Paradigm. American Economic Review 96,2: 331-36. Prasad, E., Rumbaugh, T., & Wang, Q. (2005). Putting the Cart Before the Horse? Capital Account Liberalization and Exchange Rate Flexibility in China. China and the World Economy 13, 4: 3-20. Reuters (06/10/2010). IMF head: renminbi is very undervalued. Available at http:/lblogs.reuters.com/chrystia-freeland/2010/10/06/imf-head-renminbi-is-veryundervalued/ Rossi, V. (2005). Is Revaluation of the Renminbi Good News? CESifo Forum, March, 2005. Setser, B. (2005). The Chinese Conundrum: External Financial Strength, Domestic Financial Weakness. CESifo Economic Studies, vol. 52, 2/2006. 55 Streifel, S. (2007).1mpact of China and India on Global Commodity Markets-Focus on Metals & Minerals and Petroleum. Memo, the World Bank. The Economist. (2007a). The Big Max Index: Sizzling. July 5, p.87. The Economist. (2007b). Caught between right and left, town and country: A new law on property rights defines the ideological struggle at the heart of China's economic reform. From the print edition of The Economist, Mar 8th 2007. Tilford, S. (2009). Rebalancing the Chinese Economy. Centre for European Reform Policy Brief, November 2009, London, U.K. Wang, T. (2004). Exchange Rate Dynamics. China's Growth and Integration into the World Economy: Prospects and Challenges, ed. by Eswa r Prasad, IMF Occasional Paper 232. Washington: International Monetary Fund. Wang, S. (2010). Has the Renminbi Appreciated?: Analysing the Trend of the Renminbi Exchange Rate (in Chinese). Market Analysis in International Finance, 2010.08. Wen, J. (2006). Government Work Report, Delivered at the National People's Congress meeting March 5, Beijing. World Bank (2007). China Quarterly Update (September). Washington. Available at http: I /siteresources.worldbank.org World Bank (2009). From Poor Areas to Poor People: China's Evolving Poverty Reduction Agenda. An Assessment of Poverty and Inequality in China. in Report No. 47349-CN. World Bank (2011). World Development Indicators database. Wu, N., & Q. Chen. (1992). Studies of the Renminbi Exchange Rate (Beijing: China Finance Press, 2nd edition, in Chinese). Xu, Q. (2010). Data and Perception: Is CPI the Wind or the Sail? Research Center for International Finance Policy BriefNo. 2010.077 (in Chinese). Beijing: China Academy of Social Sciences (November 9, 2010). Yi, J. (2008). Policy Options for China's Exchange Rate Regime in the Post-Reform Era. China Policy Institute & Centre for Global Finance Discussion Paper No. 26 (January), the University of Nottingham, Ningbo, China. Yin, J., Zhu, R., & Xiang, T. eds. (1991). Handbook of China's Foreign Exchange Practice (Beijing: China Finance Press, in Chinese). Yu, Y. (2007). Global Imbalances and China. Australian Economic Review, 40: 3-23. 56