POPULISM AND BROKERAGE POLITICS: AN EXAMINATION OF THE COOPERATIVE-COMMONWEALTH FEDERATIONNEW DEMOCRATIC PARTY AND THE REFORMPARTYOFCANADA by Robert Jason Morris B.A., Simon Fraser University, 1995. THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS m POLITICAL SCIENCE ©R.obert Jason Morris, 1997 UNIVERSITY OF NORTHERN BRITISH COLUMBIA April17, 1997 All rights reserved. This work may not be reproduced in whole or in part, by photocopy or other means, without the permission of the author. 11 ABSTRACT The concepts of populism and brokerage politics have been applied to many different settings, movements, and political parties. Their definitions, culled from a critical analysis of relevant books, scholarly journals, and newspaper and magazine articles, are applied to two different Canadian political parties, the Cooperative Commonwealth Federation-New Democratic Party (CCF-NDP) and the Reform Party of Canada. This application provides an interesting comparative examination of the organization, policies and Constitutions of both parties. It highlights the relationship between the two concepts concerning how a populist party can become a brokerage party due to pressures such as those experienced when in power. The application also displays the limitations with the definitions of populism and brokerage politics that make it difficult to characterize definitively any political party as populist or brokerage. The CCF-NDP and the Reform Party are neither completely populist nor brokerage. From this finding emerge several options for the CCF-NDP and the Reform Party to consider regarding their future. U1 TABLE OF CONTENTS Abstract 11 Table of Contents Ill List of Tables lV Acknowledgements v INTRODUCTION 1 Chapter One Populism and Brokerage Politics 2 1. Populism 2. Brokerage Politics 3. Conclusions 2 10 15 Populism, the CCF-NDP and the Reform Party 17 1. The Common People 2 . Power Blocs 3. Conclusions 18 24 39 Brokerage Politics, the CCF-NDP and the Reform Party 41 1. Policy Reversals 2. Expulsions and Party Discipline 3. Accommodation ofMaterial Demands 4. Conclusions 41 Chapter Two Chapter Three Chapter Four Bibliography Conclusions 43 51 57 59 64 IV LIST OF TABLES Table 1 Populism and Brokerage Politics Compared 16 v ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Upon completion of this work, I wish to thank my professors at the University of Northern British Columbia for making my studies so enjoyable. I a~ particularly grateful to my thesis committee and its supervisor, Alex Michalos. I dedicate this thesis to my parents, Bob and Arlene Morris, to my Grandfather, Bob Morris, and most importantly, to my wife, Rebecca. INTRODUCTION The Cooperative-Commonwealth Federation-New Democratic Party and the Reform Party of Canada have been discussed and written about from many different perspectives. However, the current understanding of both parties is enhanced by comparing them in the context of populism and brokerage politics. Chapter One sets out the tenets of populism and brokerage politics. Populism is then applied to the CCF-NDP and the Reform Party in the second chapter. This application illustrates the inherent limitations of populism, concentrating on the ambiguous nature of the common people and power blocs. These limitations hinder definitive classification of the CCF-NDP and the Reform Party as populist or not. Similar findings are reported after applying brokerage politics to both parties in Chapter Three. Alternative explanations for specific charges of CCF-NDP and Reform Party brokerage aspects make it difficult to label decisively either party as brokerage or not. As well, political rhetoric is a significant contributor to perceptions that certain parties are brokerage. The conclusions presented in Chapter Four sum up the problems with classifying political parties such as the CCF-NDP and the Reform Party as completely populist or brokerage. Those findings that do target specific instances of populism and brokerage politics in both parties are qualified by noting the disadvantages of comparing the CCF-NDP to the Reform Party. The relationship between populism and brokerage politics is also discussed. Populism is considered morally superior to brokerage politics. Brokerage politics is something that political parties can devolve into when their populism dissipates. The sum of the research suggests the future options for both parties. This thesis represents an important contribution to Canadian political science. First, it plainly defines populism and brokerage politics. Second, it illustrates the limitations with the concepts of populism and brokerage politics by applying them to two case studies, the CCF-NDP and the Reform Party. Third, this thesis develops a better understanding of the nature, history, policies, organization and operation of the CCF-NDP and the Reform Party of Canada. 2 CHAPTER ONE: POPULISM AND BROKERAGE POLITICS 1. POPULISM Populism is an ambiguous concept, having been applied to everything from Maoism to Ronald Reagan's political style. I It has been indiscriminately used to describe such disparate groups as North American cash-crop farmers and the narodniki of nineteenth-century Russia, as well as to twentieth century rural and urban movements in Africa, Asia and South America.2 Populism is consequently a highly general concept that needs qualification. Nevertheless, the features generally noticed when one uses the word "populist" can provide a suitable definition. Populist political parties tend to arise in opposition to perceived minority elite groups in which they feel power is concentrated. Such "power blocs," according to populists, always act in their own self-interest to the detriment of ordinary citizens, the "common people" (defined below).3 For this reason, populists blame the power blocs for the problems they identify. Populists thus often locate power blocs outside the local society in which they live, to avoid a conflict in defining themselves against their enemies, and to allow them to exaggerate their malevolence. 4 Populist parties have identified numerous groups and institutions as power blocs, including monopoly industry and finance, millionaires, industrial labour unions, interest groups, elected officials, and even bureaucrats. This broad range of targets makes the use of power bloc acceptable to describe them. A narrower term runs the risk of excluding potential power blocs identified by populist parties, by not allowing for their special characteristics. The prime example of a Canadian power bloc is Central Canada, according to many Western Canadians. Indeed, since the establishment of John A Macdonald's National Policy in 1879 that seemed to make the West an agricultural hinterland for the export of resources to Central Canada, the West 1David Laycock, Populism and Democratic Thought in the Canadian Prairies (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1990), 14; Andre Blais and Elisabeth Gidengil. Making Representative Democracy Work (Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services, 1991 ), 19. 2Peter R. Sinclair, "Class Structure and Populist Protest," in Riel to Reform, ed. George Melnyk (Saskatoon: Fifth House Publishers, 1992), 198-199. 3Roger Gibbins, Conflict and Unity (Scarborough: Nelson Canada, 1994), S-6. 4 M.J. Bateman et. al., "Mad as Hell," in Braving the New World, eds. M.J. Bateman, Manuel Mertin and David M. Thomas (Scarborough, Ontario: Nelson Canada, 1995), 73, citing Peter McCormick, "The Will of the People," in Canada and the United States, ed. David Thomas (Peterborough, Ontario: Broadview Press, 1993), 189. 3 has been a seedbed of populist movements blaming Central Canada for their problems. 5 However, what is considered a power bloc by populists, could be more perception than reality. The alleged minority elite power bloc may not be a minority, nor be composed of elites, but nevertheless is viewed this way by populists. Populist parties keep the defmition of power bloc deliberately too broad, to cover its inconsistencies, and to appeal to a broader range of people. 6 As well, populists assume that their targeted enemies form a homogenous group. For example, the Alberta Social Credit party of the 1930s identified banks and bankers as a power bloc. Yet, it is inaccurate to assume that every banker was against the common people. Surely, some common people work at banks. Furthermore, bonafide members of power blocs could perceive themselves to be of the common people. The tension produced by a blurred distinction between populists and power blocs may hamper the effectiveness and longevity of populist parties. Nevertheless, with power blocs not trusted, populism maintains a faith in the common sense and ethical wisdom of the common people. The common people are all those outside the power blocs who are not part of these scheming big interests. The common people have been historically defined in an agrarian sense, a definition that has broadened to include modem industrial workers. Originally, farmers were seen as being most genuinely of the common people because they fed and thus supported all the others.7 They did not use their capacity to exploit opportunities and make money. Instead, they were content with honest industry, independence, a frank spirit of equality, and an ability to produce and enjoy a simple abundance.s This agrarian myth of the nobility of farmers encouraged these people to perceive themselves as separate from the order of business enterprise and speculation that flourished in the cities. Rather, farmers were the innocent pastoral victims of a conspiracy hatched in the distance by a power bloc. 5Chris Adams, "The Reform Party and the Roots of Western Protest," in Canadian Politics 91/92, eds. Gregory S. Mahler and Roman R. March (Connecticut: Dushkin Publishing Group Inc., 1991), 175. 6Richard Hofstader, The Age ofReform (New York: Vmtage Books, 1955), 65. 7Laycock, 74. 8Laycock, 27; Hofstader, 8, 23 . 4 From this myth, the populist notion of an innocent and victimized populace was born that continues with the contemporary meaning of the common people. 9 The common people are now defined in more industrial times as those outside power blocs. Consequently, the common people are free from the taint of corruption and class privilege of the power blocs. In characteristic populist style, the common people are endowed with common sense and a heightened notion of justice.10 Populism accordingly views the common people as virtuous such that they need only to make their will effective for economic and social progress to follow.11 Thus, a party need only to listen to their concerns to solve the problems of the country. They should avoid engaging in political education that tries to teach the common people how their country should be. Power, then, must be returned to the common people to ensure prosperity and a humane society.12 In this sense, populism maintains a strong faith in democracy by advocating the political supremacy of the will of the common people. This can best be achieved through a "direct" relationship between the common people and leadership, unmediated by political institutions. 13 A populist democracy then, is one in which the citizens control the legislator and actively engage in the legislative process themselves. This goal could best be achieved with direct democracy (techniques advocated by the 1890s Populist movement in the United States). Direct democracy would supposedly bring the full force of the popular will into a political arena needlessly complicated by power blocs that ignore the common people. 14 In like fashion, then, central planning can conflict with populism. Even when, in democratic versions, the central plan is periodically ratified by the electorate, this system places too much authority in the hands of elite planners. Populists fear that planners are not sufficiently accountable to the common people, and could become corrupt. 9flofstader, 35. 10r.,aycock, 33 . 11 W.L. Morton, The Progressive Party in Canada (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1967 [1950]), 15; Blais and Gidengil, 19. 12Robert Lapper, Populism in British Columbia (Victoria: University of Victoria, June 10, 1991), 6. 13 Sinclair, 199; Margaret Canavan, Populism (London: Junction Books Ltd., 1981), 58; Blais and Gidengil, 19. 14Walter D. Young, Democracy and Discontent (Toronto: Ryerson Press, 1969), 10; Laycock, 37; David MacDonald, "Referendums and Federal General Elections in Canada," in Democratic Rights and Electoral Reform in Canada, ed. Michael Cassidy (Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services, 1991), 303 . 5 Nevertheless, there are two problems with any definition of the common people, concerning who is designated by this term, and its assumption of substantial consensus on key issues among the common people. First, the common people could include almost everyone. Indeed, a serious flaw of populism is that the notion of the common people, while providing a fine rallying cry, lacks any precise meaning. The common people can refer to farmers, producers, consumers, non-elites, the electorate, to the nation, to everyone except one's political opponents, or to no determinate group at all. 15 Just what do populists mean by the common people? Who do they include and exclude? While populist movements rarely explicitly define what they mean by the common people, they mean something limited. The Russian narodniki, the peasant parties of Eastern Europe, and the U.S. People's Party, all claimed to speak for the common people. However, by this they meant something more restricted and definite than "everyone." Each had definite commitments that could not be easily discarded to gain support. 16 It seems then, that who to include as the authentic common people is left open to interpretation by potential supporters. Instead, precisely defining the common people depends on ascertaining who supports (or has supported) individual instances of populist political parties. This makes it difficult to determine whether there is a critical size required before a group can be called the common people. Still, part of the ambiguity with defining the common people is because they are not usually viewed as a group. To think of them this way would make them seem to be a power bloc (which they might be). As a rhetorical device then, to show they are somehow considering the interests of each common person, populist parties try to set themselves up to listen to the common people as individuals. This requires ignoring their various group memberships. A second problem with defining the common people rests on the naive assumption that this group thinks alike. Populist movements tend to assume that the common people are a harmonious majority interest, united for like reasons against a power bloc. Yet, except in a small, homogeneous society, the common people are diverse and may disagree on many issues. In this sense, a coalition of the common people is rare, emerging only in times of war or another 15Canovan, 261 , 294-295 . 16Ibid., 274. 6 perceived grave crisis. Consequently there may be some overarching interests shared by almost everyone, but these are more the exception than the rule; widespread agreement is unusual. 17 Considering this political pluralism, the populist dream of consensus about policy matters seems illusive.1s Nevertheless, it is precisely this vagueness in defining the common people (however divided they might otherwise be) that serves to unite them under a single, populist banner. Thus, a main function of appealing to the common people is to gloss over existing political divisions and to propose a coalition. 19 Populism then, is akin to a methodology or process for discovering the will of a broad majority of people willing to unite under the general rubric of the common people to overcome a perceived common enemy.20 In this sense, populism is not an ideology in the sense of fixedly occupying a particular space on the political spectrum. Populism is not distinctively "conservative" or "liberal" then, for example, although it can be at certain moments when these terms describe the common people under scrutiny. This explains why so many disparate groups have been termed populist, since its numerous manifestations are based on whatever happens to be "the common sense of the common people" at a particular time and place. 21 The "common sense" is really a common cause or purpose to which everyone in this group is committed. Of course, the ideological mood of the common people can change. Thus to remain populist, a political party would have to adjust. Furthermore, populism can bring together different ideologies when the main focus is a perception of opposition between the common people and a power bloc.22 Thus, populism can appeal beyond ideological boundaries to individuals who perceive a kind of overarching sociocultural antagonism between themselves and some perceived or real power bloc.2 3 In this way, populism represents an attempt to create a mass political movement, mobilized around symbols 17Tom Flanagan, Waiting for the Wave (Toronto: Stoddart Books, 1995), 26. 18Flanagan, 27; John Geddes, "Populism Stalls True Reform," Financial Post, 18 March 1995, 26. 19Canovan, 262. 2Dflanagan, 2-3. 21 Ibid., 22. 22 Ibid., 137. 23 Ibid., 16. 7 and traditions congruent with some relatively popular culture, that transcend ideology in favor of expressing a group's perceived sense of threat from a power bloc. 24 A personable, strong, even messianic leader, someone who appears capable of uniting the common people and seems to embody their concerns and ideals, is often required to bring the different common people together. However, it is one thing for a leader to stand on the pulpit and profess populism, but another to be really populist. William "Bible Bill" Aberhart claimed to represent the common people, but kept tight control of the Alberta Social Credit party of the 1930s, even abandoning his populist promise of direct democracy. 25 Likewise, Juan Domingo Peron, president of Argentina (1946-1955 and 1973-1974) enjoyed massive support of a populist variety. Yet, Peron admired Italian dictator Benito Mussolini, acquired power through force, and never hesitated to use force against the common people to maintain power. 26 There is more, then, to being a real populist leader than using an appeal to the common people as an element of political strategy and rhetorical style. The populist leader's faith in the common people must extend beyond crude symbolic mass manipulation that later becomes a dictatorship over and against the common people. 27 The populist leader must represent the common people more than lead them or enforce their subjugation. However, a problem develops for populism in requiring a strong leader to help bridge ideologies with an appeal to the common people. Populism risks bringing together the worst parts of several views or ideologies. Thus, populism is often described as having a dark side. In exhibiting a distrust of the educated members of power blocs and rising against their "betters," populists claim that whatever the common people want must be right. The fear, then, is that populism can create a climate of absolutist enthusiasm bereft of compromise. The resulting tyranny of the majority could entail the sweeping aside of bureaucratic professionalism, 24 Trevor Harrison, OfPassionate Intensity (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1995), 5. 25Canovan, 102. Huey "Kingfish" Long, 1930's governor and Senator for Louisiana, appeared populist, yet he was a cynical manipulator who used this appeal to gain wealth and power, had no respect for law or constitution, and made himself virtual dictator until assassinated. 261bid., 145; Microsoft (R) Encarta (Microsoft Corporation, 1994). 27Laycock, 15; Pierre-Andre Taguieff, "Political Science Confronts Populism," Telos 103 (Spring 1995): 15, 21 ; Laycock, 15; Canovan, 261. 8 constitutional restrictions, human rights, and even due process of law.28 An unaccountable and self-interested elite power bloc might be replaced by an unaccountable, self-interested and demagogic coalition of the common people. Considering the dark side, then, it is crucial that populist leaders know how to prevent populism from developing racist or other extremist overtones.29 However, such actions might take the populism out of the coalition. Populist parties are supposed to welcome controversy in order to bring unheard feelings into the open.3° This is because a populist party's initial success depends on it offering something different. It cannot succeed simply by attaching itself to established ideas already espoused by the other parties. In this sense, populist parties, even if they appear radical, can be an important source of policy innovation. Furthermore, in calling for "extreme" changes, populist parties also appear unwilling to defer to the established system of representative government and the accompanying party system that allegedly ignores the common people.31 Indeed, one of these "radical" changes that many populist parties have called for is direct democracy that is largely incompatible with the traditions and conventions of parliamentary democracy.32 Still, while populist movements have the capacity for extremism that can prevent them from getting broad support necessary to win elections, they also have the potential to moderate ideologues. In other words, "grassroots" views or views espoused by great numbers of people can also serve as a moderating or tempering force in devising policies. This is because the common people can have common or broadly shared and non-extreme views. 33 Therefore, sometimes the political instincts of the "unwashed masses" are more moderate than their selfappointed spokespeople and would-be liberators. 34 28Canovan, 183, 203; Hofstader, 17. Such trampling of minority rights occurred in the United States, where the populist 1840s Nativist movement burned convents and harassed nuns, believing that Roman Catholicism was an international conspiracy orchestrated by the Pope. Later on, McCarthyist action against Communists in the 1950s-massively popular among Americans at the time--was made possible by the populist quality of U.S. political culture. 29preston Manning, The New Canada (Toronto: John Deyell Company, 1992), 25 . 30 Sydney Sharpe and Don Braid, Storming Babylon (Toronto: Key Porter Books Ltd., 1992), 144; Flanagan, 126. 31Canovan, 184; Paul Piccone, "Postmodern Populism," Telos 103 (Spring 1995): 76. 32MacDonald, 306. 33 Manning, 25. 34Canovan, 257; Christopher Lasch, The Revolt ofthe Elites (New York: W.W. Norton & Company, Inc., 1995), 27. After all, a lot of the Nazi SS elite reputedly held Ph.D.'s. 9 Nevertheless, because populist movements are open to so many different strains of thought, because they generalize about and stereotype power blocs, and because they intentionally resist precisely defining the common people, they have traditionally not lasted long and frequently imploded from internal conflict. 35 In this sense, populist parties seem to have a relatively short lifespan. They attempt to fulfill a purpose and often die trying. To them, then, politics is about more than being elected. The goal for populist parties is to represent people and interests that the other parties have ignored, and try to effect change according to those concerns. Thus, they may influence (or govern) the political paradigm for a time, but then usually die after their job is done. 36 Of course, though, it is possible that a populist party could continue to find new external threats with which to maintain its support and continue its mission. In summary, despite populism being an amorphous concept, a general characterization is attainable that can be applied to determine whether a political party is populist. One necessary condition that a political party must exhibit to be considered populist is confidence in the integrity, judiciousness and fairness of the common people. A party unwilling to trust the common people only represents an elitist power bloc. In this sense, another necessary condition for a populist party is that it maintains a strong faith in democracy by advocating the political supremacy of the common people. Furthermore, it is necessary for a populist party to mobilize the common people against a perceived outside threat of a power bloc. It also seems necessary for a populist party to be quite generous or vague in its specification of the common people. The clearer one is about who is or is not among the common people, the easier it becomes to target them as a special interest group, and hence, a power bloc. Finally, populist parties have a relatively limited lifespan. If the party can keep finding new populist moods or common causes to champion, though, this condition may not apply. As well, while most populist parties have been led by charismatic leaders, they could conceivably manage without one. Nevertheless, 35For example, in the United States, the People's Party (1892-1897) lasted long enough to give the American political establishment a severe shock but then quickly faded away after the Democratic party undercut its support with a candidate of populist style. Likewise in Canada, the Progressives of Alberta won enough seats in the 1921 Parliament to form the opposition but were co-opted by the Liberal Party. 36Fianagan, 23 . Brokerage parties can steal a populist party's thunder that effectively kills them. 10 despite this elaboration, our concept of populism becomes a bit hazy when the concept of brokerage politics is considered. 2. BROKERAGE POLITICS The meaning of brokerage politics has often been taken as a "given" when discussing other matters such as specific political parties. As well, brokerage politics is usually discussed regarding the negative consequences for public policy and the political system that result from its operation. Nevertheless, a plausible definition of "brokerage politics" can be ascertained following a discussion of the general characteristics usually designated by the phrase. Canada has always been a society beset with regional, cultural, religious and linguistic diversity. Because of this pluralism, successful political parties have been those able to support a wide variety of ideas and adherents. 37 Canada's federal political parties then, have been forced to offer a little to everyone in all parts of Canada to avoid polarizing society and forfeiting power.38 In this sense, the major political parties have, perhaps unconsciously, taken on an additional role of social integration to get elected. Political parties realize there is a need to harmonize and accommodate Canada's many cleavages into a stable voting coalition.39 In doing so, they perform the daunting and heroic task of maintaining social stability in an otherwise divided polity.40 The brokerage party then, aggregates a wide range of interests into a voting coalition that serves an integrative function for the political system.4 1 This is such a difficult task that brokerage politics is not always successful. To be successful, brokerage parties must therefore be selective regarding the many interests they target. Consequently, the number of voters within each group is relevant in determining whether an 37W.L. White, R. H. Wagenberg, and R.C. Nelson, Introduction to Canadian Politics and Government (Toronto: Holt, Rinehart and Winston of Canada, Limited, 1990), 85. 381bid., 88. 391bid., 87. 40Janine Brodie and Jane Jenson, "Piercing the Smokescreen," in Canadian Parties in Transition, eds. A. Brian Tanguay and Alain-G. Gagnon (Ontario: Nelson Canada, 1996), 61. 41 Gibbins, p 364-365 . 11 interest will be accommodated. The brokerage party targets the biggest interests first, and minority interests can be overlooked.42 Those playing the game of brokerage politics may lose their credibility if enough small groups are repeatedly ignored. Consequently they may find themselves unable to hold together potential coalitions. Brokerage politics is inadequate, then, when otherwise "normal politics" is marked by severe disruptions, times of turbulence when the federal political parties find themselves unable to generate a broad coalition under a single party banner. 43 For example, Canadian federal political parties did not appear to be effectively responding to the social and economic effects of the Great Depression. The resulting vacuum of leadership spurred the creation of the Cooperative Commonwealth Federation (CCF) that concentrated on helping Canadians manage during this difficult time. In turn though, brokerage parties clamor to transform themselves into the terrain of the changed political landscape.44 Thus, following the Depression, the federal Liberal Party "borrowed" many of the CCF's ideas to restore equilibrium to the brokerage system and to build a viable electoral coalition. Brokerage parties though, in constantly adapting to stay alive and avert coalition breakdowns, have not strictly adhered to an ideology. To do so could limit the amount of interests they are able to bring together that would ultimately reduce electoral success.45 Thus, insofar as political parties act as "brokers," they are essentially behaving like similar organizations opportunistically appealing to a variety of interests. Consequently, ideology may fail to distinguish either the party or its policy positions.46 Yet if ideological labels have to be attached, then brokerage parties could be called "centrist" (i.e., the less in particular they stand for, the more people can be accommodated) for occupying the middle of the political spectrum. Such centrism appeals to the largest groups in society that ensures electoral success. In contrast, populist parties, with controversial policies 42Janine Brodie and Jane Jenson, Crisis, Challenge and Change (Ontario: Methuen Publications, 1980), 4. There must be a critical size for attention, which explains why Western separatists are ignored but not Quebec separatists. 43 Brodie and Jenson, "Piercing the Smokescreen," 62. For example (with redistribution), when the larger group feels overtaxed. 44R.K. Carty, "Three Canadian Party Systems," in Party Politics in Canada ed. Hugh G. Thorburn (Ontario: PrenticeHall Canada, Inc., 1991), 133; Brodie and Jenson, "Piercing the Smokescreen," 63 . 4 5White, Wagenberg, and Nelson, 86. 46 Brodie and Jenson, "Piercing the Smokescreen," 59. 12 and a dark side, do not covertly target as many distinct interests as possible to increase their support. They deliberately exclude interests that are considered connected to power blocs, and can target the smaller, less powerful interests that brokerage parties ignore. Brokerage parties, however, can swerve to the "left" or the "right" of the political spectrum with the twists and turns of public opinion. Still, they never veer too far in either direction to avoid losing the support that keeps them in power.47 Immortality is the aim, to win as many elections as possible. Therefore, brokerage parties do not exhibit the relatively limited lifespan characteristic of many populist parties. Likewise, then, brokerage parties differ from populist parties concerning power versus change. Brokerage parties consider achieving power to be the primary aim. They are solely dedicated to assembling coalitions of voters (whatever these people demand) to deliver them to office: In contrast, populist parties tend to put effecting change ahead of winning power. In this sense, brokerage parties, unlike populist ones, tend to accept the legitimacy of the current political system (that is in large part designed to maintain their supremacy). They are thus hesitant to advocate major system reforms. Nevertheless, this pragmatic flexibility is often criticized for representing a politics of convenience. Really, brokerage parties behave as if they are predominantly concerned with doing whatever it takes to keep the ship-afloat. Thus, they constantly compete for the same policy space and the same votes, and are seen as failing to provide much choice for voters. Brokerage parties then, are similar "catch all" political parties often indistinguishable from one another, like Tweedledum and Tweedledee.48 With few major differences between the brokerage parties (e.g., the Progressive Conservatives favored a Canada-US Free Trade Agreement in 1988 while the Liberals worked on extending the North American Free Trade Agreement in 1993, and both of these parties in 47H.D. Forbes, "Absent Mandate '88," in Party Politics in Canada, ed. Hugh G. Thorburn (Ontario: Prentice-Hall Canada, Inc., 1991), 255. 48Forbes, 256; Paul G. Thomas, "Parties and Regional Representation," in Representation, Integration and Political Parties in Canada, ed. Herman Bakvis (Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services Canada, 1991), 193 . In one survey, 63% of respondents stated that political parties do not offer choice in elections because their policies are similar. Harold C. Clarke and Allan Kornberg, "Evaluations and Evolution," Canadian Journal of Political Science XXVI: 2 (June 1993): 291. 13 1996 favor giving Quebec "distinct society" status), a negative consequence is the apparent inability of Canada's party system to innovate and find solutions to new problems. 49 Since the brokerage parties all offer similar platforms, they have become concerned mainly with electorally salable images and quick fix solutions to ensure that voters choose them instead of their near-identical competitors. 5o Brokerage parties then, are afraid of new ideas and hesitate to enunciate clear policy alternatives during election campaigns. This is because they are afraid of making mistakes that could exacerbate the country's cleavages and cost them support. They thus engage in little more than incremental short-term tinkering with their policies (in contrast to populist party platforms) that can deprive the political system of an essential source of policy innovation. 51 With scant policy differentiation, brokerage parties often depend on accommodating material demands, on making electoral appeals based on uncorrelated promises to various groups. 52 In other words, brokerage parties often owe much of their success to the dispensing of patronage, perks and pork barreling to the various areas or groups among which they seek support. They become, in trying to be all things to all people, Santa Claus political parties specialized in the distribution of election goodies with clear short-term payoffs and often unexplained long-term costs. Indeed, the fiscal distress of the Canadian state regarding the deficit and debt problem is partly attributable to the pathological brokerage system.53 When brokerage politics concentrates on gaining support from coalitions through various promises, party loyalty is weakened.54 Unable to see fundamental differences between the parties, voters have few reasons to develop long-term attachments. 55 This is because brokerage politics does not tie voters in any stable way to parties, such as by ideology, principles or 49John Meisel, "The Dysfunctions of Canadian Parties," in Party Politics in Canada, ed. Hugh G. Thorburn (Ontario: Prentice-Hall Canada, Inc., 1991), 244. 50porbes, 256. Policies taking more than one term to work, such as free trade or debt reduction, are consequently avoided. 51 Forbes, 256; Joseph Wearing, Strained Relations (Toronto: McClelland & Stewart, 1990), 228; Maureen Covell, "Parties as Institutions of National Governance," in Representation. Integration and Political Parties in Canad!!, ed. Herman Bakvis (Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services Canada, 1991), 69. 52Forbes, 69. 53 John Deverell and Greg Vezina, Democracy. Eh? (Toronto: Robert Davies Publishing, 1993), 30. 54Meisel, 244; Elisabeth Gidengil, "Canada Votes," Canadian Journal ofPolitical Science XXV: 2 (June 1992): 231 ; Wearing, 59. 55Forbes, 257. 14 policies, that a populist party counts on. Brokerage politics instead encourages voters to shop around for the party that offers the best accommodation of their short-term interests. 56 Yet with weak party loyalty, once in office a brokerage political party cannot always depend on a stable basis of support for their policies.57 The different promises to different groups made by the brokerage party can later collide and erode the party's broad support. This makes them dependent on the quality of their leadership to be able to get things done. Indeed, another consequence of brokerage politics is that when political parties are hesitant to offer new policy ideas and innovations, the focus shifts from issues to leadership.58 It is the brokerage leader who must appear to embody the characteristics necessary to unite the country. The brokerage politics leader, then, in contrast to the populist leader who is supposed to follow the common people, must really lead to keep the country's numerous social cleavages together. Differences in leadership style, then, become distinguishing marks of the competing brokerage parties. The result is that elections are often viewed as being about changing personnel more than changing policies.59 In summary, brokerage politics is a strategy political parties use to gain and maintain power. This is accomplished through mediating Canada's numerous complex cleavages into a stable coalition. When successful, this strategy unites the country. When unsuccessful, minor parties arise that represent ignored interests that the brokerage parties then consider including. As well, brokerage politics, in emphasizing the need to get elected, has made parties nonideological or "centrist." Being in power indefinitely is the aim (as opposed to the relatively limited lifespan of populist parties), and therefore brokerage parties resist structural changes to the political system that could upset their supremacy. They also rely on safe policy platforms, as well as patronage, perks and pork barreling, to secure and maintain power. For this reason, brokerage politics has helped create a volatile electorate who, like consumers, shop around for the political party with the best "deals." This can mean extra attention is paid to the leaders of the brokerage parties who often constitute the primary difference among them. 56Covell, 69. 571bid. 58Forbes, 257. 59Covell, 69. 15 3. CONCLUSIONS The differences between populism and brokerage politics are set out in Table 1. · compared T abl e 1 Popu1·Ism andB ro kerage P0 rItlCS Beliefs Goal Support Ideology Policy Political System Leader Lifespan Populism Faith in democracy and the common people; opposition to power blocs; reject planning and political education Effect change Can exclude certain interests, yet attract intense support from loyal followers. Also, seek to represent the interests brokerage politics ignores Can stick to one, or bridge several Innovation (i.e., controversial policies, dark side) Critical of the current system and ways of doing things May have a strong, charismatic leader Relatively limited 16 Brokerage Politics Commitment to democracy and the need to accommodate power blocs Get elected Appeal to as many interests as possible (the largest ones that will secure electoral victory) by bridging social cleavages Not ideological; "centrist" Stagnation; accommodation of material demands Deference to the current system and ways of doing things May have a strong, charismatic leader Relatively long-lasting 17 CHAPTER TWO: POPULISM, THE CCF-NDP ANDTHEREFORMPARTYOFCANADA The Cooperative Commonwealth Federation (CCF) formed in 1932 as a confederation of several urban and rural movements. 1 The CCF never won more than 15 per cent of the popular vote federally (although found provincial success in Saskatchewan), and renamed itself the New Democratic Party (NDP) in 1961. 2 The NDP increased its provincial success, but failed to improve federally until the 1988 election, when it won 43 seats with 20.4 per cent of the popular vote. 3 In 1993, the NDP won nine seats with 6.9 per cent of the total vote. 4 NDP supporters (considering convention delegates) are predominantly middle-class, better educated than average, anglophone, male and middle-aged.5 The Reform Party of Canada was born at a 1987 conference in Vancouver, and fielded 72 candidates in the 1988 federal election (receiving two per cent of the popular vote, and no seats).6 In March 1989, Deborah Grey became the first Reform MP, winning more votes in an Alberta by-election than all her opponents combined.? Reform won 52 seats in 1993 (19 per cent of the popular vote), and placed second in 79 ridings.8 Supporters are urban and rural, better educated than average, found in almost all occupations with varying average family incomes, mostly middle-aged and male, largely English-speaking, and new to political activism.9 It is often assumed that the CCF-NDP is populist Yet, tension exists between the party's education and central planning, and the populist faith in the common people and democracy. The Reform Party tries to avoid the tension between by advocating direct democracy. The NDP 1Walter D. Young, Anatomy of a Party (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1969), 30. 2WalterD. Young, Democracy and Discontent (Toronto: Ryerson Press, 1969), 78-79. 3Alan Whitehorn, "The NDP's Quest for Survival," in The Canadian General Election of 1993, eds. Alan Frizzell, Jon H. Pammett, and Anthony Westell (Ottawa: Carleton University Press, 1994), 43 . 4Whitehom, 52. 5Alan Whitehorn, "The New Democratic Party in Convention," in Party Democracy in Canada, ed. George Perlin (Ontario: Prentice-Hall Canada, Inc., 1988), 274-276; Donald E. Blake, R.K. Carty, and Lynda Erickson, Grassroots Politicians (Vancouver: UBC Press, 1991), 59. 6 " 56 Reasons Why You Should Support the Reform Party of Canada," Reform Party of Canada, 1993. 7W.T. Stanbury, Money in Politics (Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services, 1991), 188. 8The Reformer, November 1993, 1. Reform won 17 incumbent NDP seats and beat the NDP in 173 ridings. It's second largest source of votes was former NDPers and Reform captured 200/o of potential NDP supporters. Reform spent $1.5 million to the NDP's $7.4 million. Tom Flanagan, Waiting for the Wave (Toronto: Stoddart Books, 1995), 153; Jeffrey Simpson, "The NDP has an Opportunity to Learn," Globe and Mail, 12 October 1994, A20. 9The Reformer. September/October 1991 ; Peter McCormick, "The Reform Party of Canada," in Party Politics in Canada, ed. Hugh G. Thorburn (Ontario: Prentice-Hall Canada, Inc., 1991), 347; Flanagan, 44, 159, 160. 18 is also charged with being tied to several power blocs. However, because of the ambiguity of definitions of the common people and power blocs, it is difficult to prove that the NDP is dominated by power blocs. Reform is considered to be free from power bloc links, although it ignores its potential connections. 1. THE COMMON PEOPLE At first glance, the CCF-NDP seems to have faith in the common people. It was formed by people who believed Canada needed an effective political instrument representing the people to procure social changes. IO The CCF-NDP thus claims to be dedicated to Canada's ordinary people. II However, the party's belief that people require education to see what is in their best interests conflicts with the populist faith in the common people. Indeed, the CCF-NDP has always believed that people are both rational and social creatures capable of creating utopia, if they could see what was wrong with contemporary society.12 The party consequently assumed that people could be taught to see what was best for them.13 What was best for the common people was socialism. Yet, since many of the common people disagreed, the CCF-NDP reasoned it could convince them by presenting their alternative vision.14 The party thus aimed to teach the uninformed common people the "truth" about capitalist economic and bourgeois society.15 Mildred Fahmi, a CCF founding member, said that one of the party's aims was not to acquire power, but to educate people about a new way of looking at life and the rights of people.I6 Like all political parties spreading their message, the CCF printed newspapers and distributed policy pamphlets. However, the CCF, perhaps because many of its leading figures were teachers, academics and clergymen, took standard political propaganda further. The party published study guides and reading lists of socialist books for potential converts, held 10Stanley Knowles, The New Party (Toronto: Ryerson Press, 1961), 32. 11 Knowles, 28-29, 46; Audrey McLaughlin, A Woman's Place (Toronto: Macfarlane Walter & Ross, 1992), 21- 22. 12Young, Anatomy of a Party, 45; Knowles, 12. 13 Y oung, Anatomy of a Party, 50, 52, 56; Alex Macdonald, 'My Dear Legs .. .' (Vancouver: New Star Books, 1985), 186; Judy Steed, Ed Broadbent: The Pursuit ofPower (Markham, Ontario: Viking, 1988), 98-99; Knowles, 12; "We must systematically teach them to work out their own salvation"--1935 federal campaign riding report. 14Young, Anatomy of a Party, 11, 52, 53 ; Knowles, 12; Rosemary Brown, Being Brown (Toronto: Random House of Canada Ltd., 1989), 134. 15Young, Anatomy of a Party, 52. 16George Ehring and Wayne Roberts, Giving Away a Miracle (Oakville, Ontario: Mosaic Press, 1993), 19. 19 correspondence courses, and organized study groups and ran summer schools for youth. 17 The CCF always devoted a vast amount of time and money to a unique and extensive education campaign. 18 However, tension exists between political education and populism. The CCF-NDP is taking a managerial and potentially manipulative approach to politics, by trying to create a new political community through teaching an allegedly unenlightened populace. 19 Yet, populism is about listening and reacting to the common people's concerns. It is not about telling them what should concern them. This view seems to contradict populism's faith in the common people, maintaining that individuals must look for instruction and guidance from a political party, rather than to rely upon their own resources. Such education never gave the party much more support. 20 Yet, the CCF concluded in 1948 that they were failing because they were not providing enough educational opportunities to develop socialists among newcomers. 2 1 The common people needed to be educated even more about the merits of socialism. Thus, this education continues today with NDP governments, on a smaller scale. In B.C., Premier Mike Harcourt's NDP government instituted mandatory "equity awareness" sessions for staff with the 1995 Equity Plan, and developed training programs to prevent homophobia.22 These examples show that the NDP is still interested in changing people's minds with education. Yet such action, however well-intentioned, can backfire when the state tries to impose codes of conduct on people. It is more populist to wait and let the common people autonomously change their ways. The Reform Party does not try to create optmons favorable to its policies through educating the common people. It claims to search for what bothers the common people. It then tailors its policies to these concerns. In this sense, Reform seems to believe that voters are 17Ehring and Roberts, 19; Young 51 ; Robert Tyre, Douglas in Saskatchewan (Vancouver: Mitchell Press Limited, 1962), 148. 18Young, AnatomyofaPartv, 53, 125. 19Jrving Kristol, "Socialism: Obituary for an Ideal," in The Future That Doesn't Work, ed. R. Emmett Tyrell Jr. (Washington, D.C.: University Press of America, 1977), 193 . Dave Barrett called opponents "Neanderthals." 2<>:Ehring and Roberts, 34; Young, Anatomy of a Partv, 128, 289, 290; Janine Brodie and Jane Jenson, Crisis, Challenge and Change (Ontario: Methuen Publications, 1980), 3. 21 Young, Anatomy of a Party, 51 [Report of the Education and Information Division] . 22 Steve Vanagas, "An Obsession with Race, Sex and Disabilities," B.C. Report, 22 January 1996, 10; Daniel Gawthrop, High-Wire Act (Vancouver: New Star Books, 1996), 60, 129. 20 capable of intelligently expressing their concems. 23 The CCF-NDP thinks people need to be educated, while Reform claims to believe in the "common sense of the common people." According to Reform, no expert or politician can gauge the interests of Canadians as accurately as Canadians themselves can. Parties should "Let the People Speak" and ride the waves of public opinion, instead of artificially creating support through education. 24 The differences in the two parties'· attitudes toward the common people are further evident after considering the CCF's central planning and Reform's direct democracy. For the CCF, the primary duty of the state was to secure the cultural and material welfare of the people in tangible forms such as health and education. 25 This could only be achieved with the state developing the national resources of the country under a general economic plan, free from the dictates of private interests. 26 Thus, the CCF called for a central government to set national priorities and initiate national programs. This was because the party maintained that central planning fosters both the most efficient development and the most equitable distribution of society's resources.27 In short, the CCF believed that the state must always be able to undertake major initiatives on behalf of the country.28 So, beginning in 1932, the Calgary Program of the CCF called for replacing the current economic chaos with a "planned system of social economy for the production, distribution and exchange of all goods and services."29 The founding document of the CCF, the 1933 Regina Manifesto, proposed setting up a National Planning Commission. This body would include economists, professors, engineers, statisticians and other experts, who, acting in the "public interest," would plan for the production, distribution and exchange of all goods and services necessary for the efficient functioning of the economy. 30 The 1956 Winnipeg Declaration 23 "Democratic Populism IT Task Force Report," (Reform Party of Canada, January 1996), 1. 24Flanagan, 38, 137; Jeffrey Simpson, Faultlines (Toronto: Harper Collins, 1993), 113; Preston Manning, The New Canada (Toronto: John Deyell Company, 1992), 141. 25Young, Anatomy of a Party, 109. 26lbid. [The CCF Program Today]. 27 Alan Whitehorn, Canadian Socialism (Toronto: Oxford University Press, 1992), 40; Dennis Gruending, Promises to Keep (Saskatoon: Western Producer Prairie Books, 1990), 13, 195. 28McLaughlin, 162-163. ~ Canadian Socialism, 37. 30Whitehorn, Canadian Socialism, 48; "The NDP: An Introduction," May 1991, 33-34; James McAllister, The Government ofEdward Schreyer (Kingston, Ontario: MeGill-Queen's University Press, 1984), 95 . 21 maintained that, "Private profit and corporate power must be subordinated to social planning designed to achieve equality of opportunity and the highest possible living standards for all Canadians." 31 The 1961 New Party Declaration proposed establishing an economic advisory council that would engage in central planning.32 The 1983 New Regina Manifesto endorsed central planning approved by the people and not imposed from above. 33 The 1995 Renewal Conference called for the state to regulate economic activity and redistribute wealth. 34 Current federal party leader Alexa McDonough says that the federal devolution of powers to the provinces should be rolled back, since "tougher planning and stronger measures" enable nati'?ns to manage their economies.35 Likewise, provincial wings of the NDP endorse central planning. After victory in 1971, Saskatchewan NDP Premier Allan Blakeney established a task force on developing a central planning unit. 36 Manitoba NDP Premier Ed Schreyer's three-volume 1973 report, "Guideline for the Seventies," called for setting up a "concrete planning framework [with] substantive, rational guidelines for the development of our province. "37 Central planning appears populist according to CCF-NDP rhetoric, insofar as it will replace chaotic capitalism with a planned and socialized economy owned and controlled by the people. However, central planning often involves an elite body establishing priorities and methods that have a higher authority than those presented by the common people. 38 Its complexity can require excluding the common people in favor of a small, elite group of planners. 39 Periodic elections are held in which voters can approve or reject the actions of the planners. Yet, this may not be enough to ensure accountability, and the populist, political supremacy of the common people. 3I"The NDP: An Introduction," 43 . 32Whitehom, Canadian Socialism, 47, 53 . 33 Ibid., 64. 34Edith Bramwell and Len Taylor. Vancouver Renewal Conference: Partv Principles Draft Discussion Paper, 1995, 2 [http://www.fed .ndp.ca]. 35Richard Starr, "Iron Angel," Canadian Forum, September 1995, 17, 18. This must go over well in Quebec! 36Gruending, 56, 88. 37McAilister, 71 . Schreyer's government also engaged in planning with Autopac and mineral exploration. 38David Laycock, Populism and Democratic Thought in the Canadian Prairies (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1990), 179; Blake, Carty, and Erickson, 6; Whitehorn, Canadian Socialism, 180. ~ Canadian Socialis!!!, 39; Robert Lapper, Populism in British Columbia (Victoria: University of Victoria, 1991), 18. 22 Indeed, countless examples in other socialist states show the danger of corruption and excessive concentration of power with central planning. Likewise in Canada, 63.8 per cent of federal NDP delegates at the 1983 convention felt that direct political action is sometimes necessary in place of democratic, electoral politics.40 Earlier, Tommy Douglas tried to give Department of Agriculture surveyors the right to enter any land in the province without the owner's consent.41 In B.C., Dave Barrett's NDP in the early 1970s passed an order-in-council "freezing" large sections of the province from being used for non-agricultural purposes. This was criticized for violating the democratic right to hold and sellland.42 Still, the actions undertaken by NDP planners are not strictly decided by entirely unaccountable elites. Party members, the NDP's common people, decide NDP policy every second year at party conventions. The NDP Constitution affirms that the convention has final authority over federal policy, programs and Constitution. 43 Yet, conventions are for party members sympathetic to NDP goals. An NDP government must consider the interests of many common people who are not NDP members. Besides, NDP convention delegates are not all common people in the populist sense of joining the party as individuals. Representatives of organized labour, for example, are guaranteed convention representation (discussed below). These may be common people, but they attend because of their labour connection. Reform Party policy conventions are also held biennially. 44 Riding associations submit resolutions (in 1996, there were four constitutional resolutions and 49 policy resohttions) to be voted on by all delegates. With limited time, only six speakers are allowed to express themselves per resolution. This hurried pace (characteristic of all party conventions) may inadequately let Reform's common people properly and democratically work out party policy. Also, like CCF-NDP conventions, Reform policy may not accurately reflect the views of the many common people not belonging to Reform. To overcome this, Reform supports direct 40Whitehorn, "The New Democratic Party in Convention," 290. 41 Tyre, 209. 42Lorne J. Kavic and Garry B. Nixon, 1200 Days (Coquitlam: Kaen Publishers, 1978), 98, 249. 4 3The Constitution of the NDP, 1993 [Art. V(2)]. 44 The Constitution of the Reform Party of Canada, 1995 [Art. 7(b)]. 23 democracy, including binding referenda on governments, for moral issues such as abortion and capital punishment, and for constitutional change.45 Consequently, Reform claims it will put its policies on the line with direct democracy. A referendum could have stopped the Reform-supported 1988 Free Trade Agreement that was, according to some polls, only supported in three provinces. Likewise, referenda could work against the interests of less populated regions. This could violate Reform's belief in provincial equality.46 These examples show that citizens not supportive of a Reform government would have the opportunity, along with elections, to override the preferences of the common people who make Reform policy at its conventions. Unlike the CCF-NDP, then, Reform seems populist for deferring to the will of all the common people, despite its policies.47 The CCF-NDP, alternatively, has often been reluctant to allow its policies to be overturned. For example, the B.C. NDP, not favoring direct democracy, refuses to submit to referendum the secretly developed 1996 Nisga'a Agreement in Principle land claims deal. 48 NDP Aboriginal Affairs Minister John Cashore said a province-wide referendum on such a complex agreement would be a divisive, destructive exercise.49 Nevertheless, considering the great number and variety of issues facing contemporary governments, it is unclear how well such direct democracy could perform in assuring the political supremacy of the common people. Critics of direct democracy say it can be manipulated by elites. Who decides what questions are put to referendum? Who decides the wording of the questions? Could special interest groups hijack the referendum process? Reform has to prove these concerns do not reduce the populist sovereignty of the common people. It tries to do this, by favoring the use of initiative. 45 "Democratic Populism ll Task Force Report," 3, 6-7; "56 Reasons"; "Platform and Statement of Principles of the Reform Party," 1988, 11 ; Flanagan, 26. A referendum requires a simple majority of voters, plus a simple majority in at least seven provinces. Reform called for a referendum on the Meech Lake Accord. 461bid. 47The exception: Manning's equality of individuals policy. This is addressed in Chapter 3. 48 Steve Vanagas, "A Race-Exclusive Para-State," B.C. Report, 26 February I996, 8. Glen Clark opposes referenda because "substance is everything." Bob Rae wouldn't allow another Charlottetown Accord referendum because it was "out of control. " Rick Hiebert, "Two Cheers for Direct Democracy," B.C. Report. 13 May 1996, 11 ; Susan Delacourt, United We Fall (Toronto: Penguin Books, I994), 120. 49Terry O'Neill, "The NDP Obviously Thinks," B.C. Report. II March 1996, 2. 24 According to Reform's initiative, three per cent of eligible voters of Canada can sign a petition requesting that a question or legislative proposal be placed on the ballot as a referendum at the next federal general election.50 With initiative, Reform seems populist for letting the common people help set the policy agenda. Conversely, Harcourt's B.C. NDP, forced by referendum to introduce initiative, made it practically impossible to use. 51 For this, the NDP appears hesitant to let the common people set the government's priorities. (.Still, initiative, like referenda, could be overused, contributing to voter bum-out and apathy. Initiative could also be abused by the common people. It could allow them to force their "pet projects" onto a national agenda (the dark side of populism). Special interest groups could use initiative against the common people. Also, one region could force a national referendum on an issue detrimental or unimportant to the rest of Canada. This is because Reform's initiative does not specify where the three per cent of voters must live. The common people cannot be entirely politically supreme with Reform's initiative until these problems with it are overcome. 2. POWER BLOCS The CCF power bloc was plain to see--the men who controlled the fmancial structure of Canada, those who suffered little during the depression. Capitalism was the cancer eating at the heart of society, and CCF members blamed it for the social order's most alarming ailments, proclaiming that no CCF government would rest until it had "eradicated capitalism."52 The Conference Resulting in the Formation of the CCF reported that the Great Depression was due to the inherent unsoundness of the capitalist system. 53 The 1933 Regina Manifesto called for replacing the "capitalist system with its inherent injustice and inhumanity. "54 The 1956 Winnipeg Declaration described capitalism as "immoral. "55 Future party leader Edward Broadbent in 1970 called for abandoning the "moral hogwash" that is 50 "Democratic Populism n Task Force Report, II 6; "56 Reasons. II 3% is the usual American standard. 51 B.C. NDP initiative requires 10% of eligible voters in all 75 Tidings, who must sign the initiative in 90 days. Then, the initiative is put on a ballot and needs a double majority (a simple majority plus a majority in two-thirds of the Tidings). The NDP then still does not have to enact the initiative proposal into law. Steve Vanagas, "Digging in Against Direct Democracy," B.C. Report, 6 December 1993, 6. 52Young, Democracy and Discontent, 63; Leo Zakuta, A Protest Movement Becalmed (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1964), 37; Laycock, 164; Young, Anatomy of a Party, 44. 53 Young, Anatomy of a Party, 42. Note that it is big business and monopolies the CCF was primarily against. 54"The NDP: An Introduction," 33 . 55Whitehorn, Canadian Socialism, 47. 25 capitalism.56 The NDP today, to a lesser degree, still targets capitalism as a power bloc. For instance, the 1995 Renewal Conference reported that unrestrained capitalism produces intolerable levels of social and economic inequality. 57 The CCF-NDP has consistently seen "Big Business" and capitalism as power blocs. Yet, Reform charges that the NDP is not populist, because it is connected to several other power biocs (labour, special interest groups, Charlottetown Accord elites, Quebec, Central Canada, and high taxes). 58 For this, the NDP loses some populist, direct connection to the common people, but is not dominated by any power blocs. The perception of captivity is largely due to the ambiguous definitions of the common people and power blocs. Reform works hard at keeping a direct link between itself and the common people, but ignores its potential links with power blocs, including Western Canada. One reason for creating the NDP from the CCF, was that the party had not found a large and growing audience. 59 As well, membership fees and subscriptions from the common people did not provide the CCF much money, and election campaigns were getting expensive.60 So, after the 1958 Progressive Conservative-John Diefenbaker landslide and resultant CCF disappointment, the party thought it needed formal labour support. 61 Luckily at this time, the Canadian Labour Congress had just formed from the Canadian Congress of Labour and the Trades and Labour Congress. This new body officially agreed to join the fight against capitalism with the CCF, now rechristened the NDP. 62 Hence today, organized labour has a position of influence within the NDP. The federal NDP's Constitution guarantees representation to organized labour. Article Ill(2) allows affiliated membership with trade unions. 63 The party's Federal Council, which runs the party between conventions, reserves about ten per cent of its seats for labour (not including 56Ed Broadbent, The Liberal Rip-off (Toronto: New Press, 1970), x . 57Bramwell and Taylor, 2. 58 Act ofFaith (Vancouver: B.C. Report Magazine Ltd., 1991), 59, 176. 59Whitehorn, Canadian Socialism, 51 . 60Joseph Wearing, Strained Relations (Toronto: McClelland & Stewart, 1990), 187; K.Z. Paltiel, Political Party Financing in Canada (Toronto: McGraw-Hill Company of Canada Limited, 1970), 48. 61 Imperfect Union, National Film Board, 1989 [video]. The CCF won 8 seats (9.5% total vote) in 1958. 62Knowles, 14, 18. 63The Constitution of the NDP. 26 labour members not designated as such). 64 Article X establishes a Council of Federal Ridings that promotes the federal NDP in the provinces and territories. This body is guaranteed labour representation, with the amount determined by the council. 65 Trade unions also receive one convention deiegate per 1000 members, under Article V(4).66 Thus, labour deiegates at conventions typically constitute about 25 per cent of total delegates (not including the many labour members who are not classified as "representatives" oflabour unions). 6 7 Labour can also submit policy resolutions to conventions. 68 Within the party, union representation constitutes 20 to 25 per cent of executive and officer positions. 69 Also, labour is provided access to caucus meetings that other parties keep closed. 70 Labour also provides the NDP with much-needed funds. During federal election years, trade unions contribute between $1.5 million and $2.1 million to the federal NDP.7 1 This does not include unreported financial donations to the NDP's federal office, and does not place a dollar value on many in-kind contributions. 72 Financial support from labour to the federal NDP in non-election years (from 1974-1990) has accounted for up to 20 per cent or total revenue.7 3 Furthermore, Article IV(3) of the NDP Constitution allows the party to receive $0.20 per month from participating union workers belonging to NDP-affiliated unions. 74 This accounted tor 11 percent of the party's federal budget in 1990.75 Provincial NDP governments also receive substantial labour funding. In 1969, actual expenditures by Ed Schreyer's Manitoba NDP totaled $45,321 when actual revenue was $30,761: unreported labour donations made up the difference. 76 Likewise, the B.C. Liberal Party released 64lbid. [Art. Vll(l)(f)]. Labour gets one member for each of the 15 unions with the most affiliated members. 65 lbid. 66lbid. Each federal riding gets one voting delegate for every 50 members. 67Keith Archer, "The New Democrats, Organized Labour and the Prospects of Electoral Reform," in Canadian Political Parties, ed. Herman Bakvis (Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services, 1991), 316, 321; Keith Archer, "The NDP: A Trade Union Party?" in Canadian Political Party S)!stems, ed. R.K. Carty (Peterborough, Ontario: Broadview Press, 1992), 390. 68The Constitution of the NDP [Art. V(4)(1)]. 69Archer, "The NDP: A Trade Union Party," 392. 70Archer, "The New Democrats, Organized Labour," 316, 321. 71Archer, "The NDP: A Trade Union Party," 395 . 72 lbid. 73Archer, "The New Democrats, Organized Labour," 335 . 74The Constitution of the NDP. 75 Archer, "The New Democrats, Organized Labour," 335; Stanbury, 167. 76McAllister, 135. 27 a list oflabour support for Glen Clark's 1996 B.C. NDP leadership campaign. The party alleged that Clark (not denying the charge) received $1500 each from 64 union locals.77 For the May 1996 election, Elections Canada revealed that Clark's NDP received $735,000 from unions.78 Vancouver Sun columnist Vaughn Palmer claims that further labour contributions of $650,000 are not included, because they were directly donated to NDP candidates.79 These links to labour seem to prevent the NDP from being thoroughly populist. The party appears formally and structurally linked to labour as a power bloc.80 It seems to take its cues from the labour movement instead of the common people. 8 1 Indeed, the NDP focused on free trade in the 1993 election after being chastised by labour for not doing so in 1988.82 However, this is only a perception of captivity to a labour power bloc. Organized labour does not dominate the NDP. Indeed, union affiliation rates have never been substantial, comprising 14.6 per cent of unions in 1963, and only 7.3 per cent in 1984.83 While the NDP gets a significant amount of money from unions, it also has other revenue sources. Besides, all unionists and labour leaders may not be united in opposition against the common people. Really, there are many common people in unions. Thus, a labour link would connect the NDP with many common people. Reform critics would be ignoring these common people in spurning such a tie. Yet, the NDP has never attracted much "grassroots" labour support. It mostly receives support from labour leaders.84 A 1962 Gallup survey after the recent federal election found that voters from trade union homes split 23 per cent for the NDP and 68 per cent for the Tories and 77 Steve Vanagas, "Names the NDP Doesn't Want You to Know," B.C. Report, 25 March 1996, 9. 78 "Labour, Business Take Sides," B.C. Report, 16 September 1996, 10. Individuals gave $2.8m, business: $120,000. 79Ibid. 80 Imperfect Union [Jo Surich]; Whitehorn, Canadian Socialism, 15; Lapper, 13 . Canadians fear "Big Labour" even more than "Big Business" that the CCF-NDP rallies against. 81 Macdonald, 68. Hazen Argue left the NDP in 1962 due to labour domination. Joyce Meissenheimer of the S .C. NDP's provincial executive said in 1972 that, "We elected [an NDP] government to legislate on the side of labour." Harcourt's B.C. NDP had a union-only Vancouver Island Highway upgrade in 1994. Its Fait Wage Policy forces contractors on public construction jobs to pay union rates. Tyre, 96-97; Kavic and Nixon, 65; Tom McFeely, "Actions Speak Louder than Words," B.C. Report, 29 April 1996, 8; Vanagas, "Names the NDP Doesn't Want You to Know," 8. 82Ehring and Roberts, 7, 19, 221 , 333; "Issues: A Voter's Guide," Vancouver Sun, 23 October 1993, AlO. 83Whitehorn, Canadian Socialism, 15. 84Jmperfect Union. 28 Liberals. 85 The 1993 federal election saw an exodus of rank-and-file union members from the NDP to Reform.86 Overall, most trade unionists--the common people in labour--do not vote NDP. 87 Besides, populist parties are supposed to be set up to listen to the common people as individuals, not as members of a group such as labour. Yet, the NDP Constitution guarantees organized labour special influence. Nevertheless, the NDP maintains its connection with labour that is in tension with populism. It has embarked since 1995 on a national affiliation drive. 88 New leader Alexa McDonough says that, "Our brothers and sisters in the labour movement are part of our family and there ain't going to be no divorce."89 In contrast, the Reform Party has explicitly avoided any formal link with labour. Reform's Constitution only allows individuals to join. 90 Furthermore, it does not have quotas for convention delegates representing certain interests such as labour. Delegates are chosen by one delegate per 40 riding members up to 240 members, then one delegate for each additional100 members.9I Reform may have no connections to labour, but Audrey McLaughlin claimed that Reform is tied to the "corporate agenda" and oil companies.92 Yet, Reform also tries to avoid being linked to business as a power bloc. Reform promises to eliminate grants, handouts, and tax concessions to private corporations. 93 Of course, Reform has to fulfill these populist promises if it ever forms a government. Besides, the NDP accepts corporate cash. In 1974, the NDP received $14,204 in corporate contributions, and in 1988, raised $262,524 from corporations. 94 In 1995, corporations gave the NDP $425,000 for only 9 MPs.95 However, the party claims to ensure that such 8 5Steed 94 86Aiexa' ~ and Ray Whitehead, Vancouver Renewal Conference: Party Relations Draft Discussion Paper, 1995, 2 [http://www.fed.ndp.ca]. 87Jack MacDonald, "The New Democratic Party," in The Canadian Voter's Guidebook, [no ed. given] (Toronto: Fitzhenry and Whiteside Limited, 1972), 49; Imperfect Union. 88McDonough and Whitehead, 4. 89 starr, 11. 90The Constitution of the Reform Party of Canada, [Art. 2(c)] . 91 Ibid. [Art. 7(d)]. 92 Act ofFaith, 113 . Statement by McLaughlin made in 1990. 93 Act of Faith, 113; "Principles and Policies of the Reform Party," 1995, 12; "56 Reasons"; Deborah Grey, "Security at Home and Work are Reformer's Themes," Vancouver Sun, 27 February 1996, Al3. 94Stanbury, 170, 489-91 . 95Ciyde Graham, "Corporate Canada Bankrolls Liberals," Prince George Citizen, 6 July 1996, 5. 29 donations (to provincial wings) are from businesses with good labour practices that also agree with NDP policy. 96 As well, in several cases, NDP party policy forbids the acceptance of any funds from corporations (or at least from "large" corporations). Still, to get around this, the B.C. I NDP in the 1970s accepted corporate money through non-profit societies. 97 Ed Schreyer's Manitoba NDP promised not to accept corporate donations above $500, and was bound by the Manitoba Election Act to refuse any corporate contributions for election campaigns. 98 Such money, then, was simply not reported. It was laundered through a trust fund or "donated" by the federal NDP.99 As well, dozens of party members resigned from the Ontario NDP in protest of that party's proposal to accept corporate donations. 100 Bob Rae's NDP received 57 corporate donations of$2000 or more in 1991.101 Reform, then, can charge that the NDP has an anti-populist link to corporations. Reform typically receives about 90 per cent of its funds from supporters. 102 The NDP usually gets about 40 per cent of revenue from individuals, yet two-thirds of these are extracted from union dues and payroll deductions.103 Still, Reform accepted $570,000 from corporations in 1994 (10 per cent oftotal revenue), and $815,000 in 1995 (nearly double the federal NDP total, with not even being government).I04 To be completely populist, Reform and the NDP would have to reject all corporate money. Still, the amount of corporate donations received by the NDP and Reform may not compare to the much larger amount of donations accepted by other parties. Besides a labour link, the NDP began looking for new ways to increase its support. This is exemplified by the selection of Audrey McLaughlin to replace leader Edward Broadbent in 1989. McLaughlin, by her own admission, had little support or ties from the labour wing of the %Stanbury, 169. 97Terry O'Neill, "The NDP's Corporate-cash Ban Reveals a Neanderthal Mindset," B.C. Report, 8 Aprill996, 2. 98McAllister, 13 7. 99Ibid. In 1975, the federal NDP "transferred" $252,421 to the Manitoba NDP. ICJO:Ehring and Roberts, 89. 101 Ian McLeod, Under Siege (Toronto: James Lorimer and Company, Ltd., 1994), 11. 102The Reformer, September 1995, 4; Lome Gunter, "Put Your Money Where Your Vote is," B.C. Report, 27 July 1992, 13. 103 Stanbury, 193; Gunter, 13; "Corporate Donors Cold-Shoulder Reform," Vancouver Sun, 10 February 1996, A4. 104Graham, 5; "Corporate Donors Cold-Shoulder Reform." 30 party, and had little background in the trade union movement. 105 She appeared more linked to the next set of power blocs that the NDP aligned itself with, environmental and feminist organizations. The NDP's Constitution allows affiliated membership with farm groups, cooperatives, women's organizations and other groups that abide by the NDP's principles.106 Thus, the party supports special interest groups playing a consultative role in developing party policy, and endorses alliances with them in obtaining mutual objectives. 107 Audrey McLaughlin said she welcomes special interest groups, because policy is improved when more "interests" are brought into the decision-making process.I 08 Special interest groups can be permanent or temporary, single issue pressure groups. Their functions include representing issues that parties or governments ignore, policy advocacy, and policy participation. So, the NDP of the 1990s focuses on the concerns of various special interest groups, particularly concentrating on feminist and environmental issues. For instance, the 1983 New Regina Manifesto states that ecological priorities should guide technological and economic decisions to ensure natural resource conservation. 109 Thus, Harcourt's B. C. NDP introduced the toughest pulp mill pollution laws in Canada, protected millions of hectares of wilderness, and planned to double the proportion of provincial park lands by 2000 to include 12 per cent of Vancouver Island. 110 In taking up feminist issues, Dave Barrett's 1972-1975 B.C. NDP was the first provincial government to fund rape relief centres, transition houses and women's health collectives, and even created a committee to eliminate sexism in textbooks and curriculum. III In Saskatchewan, 105McLaughlin, 59, 76. McLaughlin was possibly chosen as a "special interest." Nelson Riis said "it was time to choose a woman." Delegates were called "sexist" for supporting a male leader. Dave Barrett and William Miller, Barrett (Vancouver: Douglas & Mcintyre, 1995), 85, 170, 183; Whitehorn, "The NDP's Quest For Survival," 48. 106The Constitution of the NDP [Art. ill(2)]. 107McDonough and Whitehead, 2. 108McLaughlin, 22. I09wrutehorn, Canadian Socialism, 62. llOGawthrop, 128, 129, 185. 111 Brown, 99, 130, 132, 138. Still, Barrett is not known for respecting the opposite sex. Rosemary Brown said the Premier often made sexist remarks (he once called reporter Marjorie Nichols a "venomous bitch"). Barrett even won a Male Chauvinist Pig award. Barrett and Miller, 85 . 31 Alan Blakeney instituted major social programs concerning affirmative action for women during his 1978-1982 term.m The federal NDP has also taken up the concerns of feminist special interest groups. The 1983 New Regina Manifesto calls for addressing gender discrimination and inequality, and violence against women. 113 The party has a detailed affmnative action policy that requires female candidates in at least 60 per cent of the ridings where the NDP might win. 114 Audrey McLaughlin also said an equal Senate must have half the seats held by women. 115 As well, there is a Participation of Women Committee to encourage female involvement in the NDP. 116 Focusing on the concerns of various special interest groups appears to move the NDP further away from populism. It appears that the NDP takes its policies from whatever group is protesting in front of the legislature. 117 The NDP seems to listen to the power bloc of special interest groups, instead of the common people. However, this perception ignores the common people in special interest groups. As well, since special interest groups engage in policy advocacy, it is natural that they would try to get parties like the NDP to promote their causes. Besides, the link to the NDP could be coincidental. Some special interest groups and the NDP may have much in common in their goals and policies. Conversely, there are special interest groups, REAL Women, for example, that are not associated with the NDP. It cannot be proved, then, that special interest groups dominate the NDP. Still, the populist requirement of autonomy from power blocs is broken because the NDP Constitution allows for affiliated membership with special interest groups. Except for this, the charge that the party is captive to special interest groups is a rhetorical tactic of Reformers trying to demonstrate their relatively more "pure" link to the common people. 112Gruending, 218. 113Wbitehorn, Canadian Socialism, 62. 114"New Democratic Party Nomination and Affirmative Action Policy," 26 May 1996. In 1993, a similar policy barred men from nomination in some ridings. 115McLaughlin, 165. 116Wbitehorn, "The NDP's Quest for Survival," 49; McLaughlin, 54. 117Desmond Morton, "The Bitter Fruit of Power," Maclean's, 12 July 1993, 20; Paul Piccone, "Postmodem Populism," Telos 103 (Spring 1995): 53 . 32 Indeed, the Reform Party has always claimed to have no formal links to special interest groups, which they call "special interests."IIs Reform sees "special interests" as minority organizations pushing their "radical" views onto the silent majority of unsuspecting common people. The party does not consider the many common people belonging to these organizations. So, Reform promises to end all government spending on them. 119 According to Reformers, special interest groups should question their existence if they cannot find fmancial support from those they purport to represent. For this, Reform does not appear to be coupled to special interest groups. It is instead picketed by them. The Coalition Against the Reform Party, for example, is solely dedicated to denouncing Reform. Yet, the members of Reform could be in some ways construed as a special interest group. For instance, many Reformers resent gun control and belong to firearms' groups. Could they thus be perceived as being tied to the gun lobby? Also, is Reform wedded to market capitalism, social conservatism, the pro-choice movement, or leader Preston Manning's religious beliefs? These accusations are as hard to prove as arguing that the NDP is dominated by "special interests." Yet, Reform defines a "special interest" as those groups not fitting its world view. It does not examine its own possible connections to special interest groups as power blocs. Still, such links to Reform are not formal affiliations with the party. Members join Reform as individuals. With the CCF-NDP Constitution, special interest groups can have formal affiliation. Reform, though, could still be taken informally hostage by special interest groups, if enough members joined from one group. Special interest groups have also focused on constitutional reform. The NDP has taken a similar interest, by supporting the Charlottetown Accord. On September 24, 1991, the government tabled in the House of Commons the Canada Round package of constitutional proposals. 120 The proposals were discussed and debated, in typical Canadian fashion, by a committee. This was followed by a few open public forums that were superseded by closed-door 118David Laycock, "Reforming Canadian Democracy?" Canadian Journal of Political Science XXVII: 2 (June 1994): 217; Richard Sigurdson, "Preston Manning and the Politics ofPostmodernisrn," Canadian Journal of Political Science XXVII: 2 (June 1994): 267. l1 9"Principles and Policies," 11 ; "56 Reasons" ; Simpson, 123 . 12<>:Brooke Jeffrey, Strange Bedfellows. Trying Times (Toronto: Key Porter, 1993), 45. 33 agreements among provincial premiers (three of them NDP), who constructed a deal to be approved or rejected on October 26, 1992. 121 The NDP, provincially and federally, decided to support the Accord. The party consequently placed itself on the same team as the mainstream political parties including the Liberals and Conservatives, all the provincial premiers and territorial leaders, aboriginal leaders, most special interest groups, business groups (so much for the capitalist power bloc), labour leaders, the media, and the cultural elite.I22 Unfortunately, according to conventional interpretation, the common people did not identify with the "Yes" side. They did not buy their scare tactics (Bob Rae called detractors "snake-oil salesmen"; Glen Clark felt "fear for the future of this country" if the Accord failed). 123 As a result, 54 per cent of Canadians--the common people with home-made signs and little coordinated campaigning, spending a fraction of the $10 million spent by the other side--ignored the advice of the political parties, all 11 governments, the media, banks, labour, every established authority, and voted "No."l24 The NDP quickly found it was out of touch with ordinary Canadians. In the NDP's Western heartland, the vote was massively "No," especially in British Columbia where the federal NDP had 19 seats.12s Audrey McLaughlin's Yukon riding voted massively "No," as did many other NDP strongholds. 126 Thousands of NDP members and 58 per cent of NDP supporters voted against their own party.I27 Again, the NDP did not appear populist. The Accord was a complex agreement that Canadians defeated for many different reasons. Yet, it came to symbolize a massive rejection of the so-called elites of the country that supported the deal. 128 The NDP found itself belonging to 121 Ibid., 45-54. 122Ehring and Roberts, 314; McLeod, vii; John Deverell and Greg Vezina, Democracy. Eh? (Toronto: Robert Davies Publishing, 1993), 105; Lawrence Leduc and John H. Pammett, "Referendum Voting," Canadian Journal of Political Science XXVII: 1 (March 1995): 9, 11 ; Delacourt, 71 ; Brooke, 115, 128, 129, 148, 194. 123Brooke, 170; Steve Vanagas, "Big Labour's Best Bet," B.C. Report, 22 January 1996, 9. 124Brooke, 1, 2, 114-115, 134; Ted Byfield, "Harcourt Misuses Power of Law," Halifax Daily News, 16 June 1995, 26; Gawthrop, 79. 125Whitehorn, "The NDP's Quest for Survival," 48; B.C. voted 68.3% against, the highest in Canada. 126Brooke, 6. 127Ehring and Roberts, 316; McLeod, 62; LeDuc and Pammett, 26. 12llNorman Penner, "The Past, Present, and Uneasy Future of the New Democratic Party," in Canadian Parties in Transition, eds. Brian A Tanguay and Alain-G. Gagnon (Ontario: Nelson Canada, 1996), 100. 34 this spurned power bloc, when it could have been the champion of the common people by supporting the "No" side. However, the perception that the NDP is tied to this power bloc of Canadian elites is easier to feel than to prove. It is naive to assume that Accord rejection and support was polarized between the common people and the elites. Some common people probably liked the agreement. Also, people from labour or special interest groups voted against the Accord. The NDP cannot be totally captive to these power blocs by campaigning against many of their members. Furthermore, Canadians did not consider party allegiance when deciding which way to vote. 129 The Accord, then, may be better seen as non-elites versus elites, rather than the common people versus a power bloc. The Reform Party, however, strategically argued that the Charlottetown Accord showed how the other parties, including the NDP, were out of touch with the common people. However, Reform, like the NDP, also had a difficult time determining its position on the agreement. Manning initially hesitated to join the "No" side after pledging an end to "constitutional wrangling. "130 As well, there was significant initial support for the deal based on early polls.m Yet, instead of jumping on the "Yes" side like the NDP, Reform opted for a more careful and populist approach. Reform decided to find out from its supporters and other Canadians what side to take. Telephone "hotlines" and party member mail-outs started overwhelmingly shouting "No." Thus, Reform decided to become the only federal party against the deal, the only party supposedly representing the common people.132 As well, 96 per cent of Reform Party identifiers voted "No."133 Unlike the NDP then, Reform did not appear to link itself with this power bloc of elites. Of course, this was mostly a power bloc that Reform helped create to display its alleged populist virtues. 129arooke, 6. 130flanagan, 28, 102, 103, 107. 131LeDuc and Pammett, 9. 132Flanagan, 104. 133LeDuc and Pammett, 26. 35 The Charlottetown Accord was one attempt of many for bringing Quebec into the constitutional fold and reducing the separatist threat. Yet, by this time, many common people were tired of national politics being dominated by constitutional issues. They were fed up with political parties devoting what they perceived to be excessive resources to Quebec's demands. Despite this populist mood, the NDP has long placated Ia belle province. It set the standard, endorsing a constitutional resolution giving Quebec "special status" in 1967.134 Later, the party supported the 1987 Meech Lake Accord (with Ed Broadbent signing). 135 This deal tried to give Quebec constitutional recognition of "distinct society," a constitutional veto, the right to opt out of federal spending programs with full financial compensation, a role in appointing Supreme Court judges, and more control over immigration. 136 As well, the NDP, in designing and supporting the Charlottetown Accord, endorsed a document that again tried to give Quebec constitutional "distinct society" status, plus a guarantee of one quarter of House of Commons seats. 137 However, in treating Quebec as a province unlike the others, the NDP appears linked to Quebec as a power bloc that prevents it from adequately listening to the common people from other regions. Of course, though, there are many common people in Quebec who are also federalists. The vague definition of power bloc overlooks this inconsistency. Yet, considering the constitutional deals the party supported, the NDP created an image for itself that it is captive to the intelligentsia of Quebec, the ones who are calling for special status. As well, the NDP Constitution allows for closely connected provincial NDP parties. 138 Yet, the Quebec wing gets separate mention in Article Xlll, where federal NDP involvement in Quebec is also affirmed.I39 Deliberate sections for Quebec in the party's chief document show how the NDP focuses on one 134Steed, 117. This convention resolution resulted in a shower of attacks on the NDP for giving in so easily to Quebec, and prompted Eugene Forsey, a former research director of the CLC, to quit the NDP. 135 Sydney Sharpe and Don Braid, Storming Babylon (Toronto: Key Porter Books Ltd., 1992), 154; Act of Faith, 243; Steed, 302; Delacourt, 105. 136F. L. Morton, "The Living Constitution," in Introductory Readings in Canadian Government and Politics, eds. R. M. Krause and R. H. Wagenberg (Mississauga, Ontario: Copp Clark Pitman Ltd., 1991), 62. The NDP supported this deal made in secret, with no public input allowed since it was a "seamless web" not amenable to any changes. 137Consensus Report on the Constitution, 1992 [The Charlottetown Accord]. Sections 2(c) and 21(a). 138The Constitution of the NDP [Art. XII]. 139Ibid. 36 province, as a potential power bloc, when the populist mood resents catering to any provinces, especially Quebec. Unlike the NDP, Reform opposed the Meech Lake Accord and the Charlottetown Accord.140 Reform also has a "Plan B" for Quebec separation that dares to ask what will happen if Canada fragments.I 4 1 In place of appearing to cater to every demand made by Quebec, then, Reform argues that concessions tear the country apart. Instead, it is time to call separatist bluffs. This tough stance strikes a responsive chord in many common people, even if others insist it may drive Quebec out of Confederation. I42 Not appearing captive to one province like the NDP, then, Reform policy affirms a commitment to Canada as one nation, as a balanced federation of equal provinces.143 To ensure provincial equality, Reform favors the Triple 'E' Senate (equal, elected, effective), and even won an anomalous Senate seat by election in 1988.144 An equal Senate will provide for regional representation in a federal system. It would also give a voice to the many common people who believe that Canadian politics are dominated by Central Canada and Quebec. However, it could allow a tyranny of the minority in which the interests of all common people are not considered. The common people in a sparsely populated region might be able to block or delay policies supported by the population-based, majoritarian House of Commons. In this sense, Reform's Triple 'E' Senate could, in anti-populist and undemocratic fashion, give a minority of common people in a small province equal status with the majority of common people in the larger provinces. Nevertheless, the NDP has never been as concerned with provincial equality in Parliament. It would eliminate the Senate. Saskatchewan NDP Premier Blakeney feared an effective upper house would delay important changes that Parliament wanted to make.1 45 Ontario NDP Premier Bob Rae delayed Senate reform talks during the formulation of the 140Sharpe and Braid, 154; Manning, 243; The Reformer, June 1994. l41"20/20: A Vision for the Future of Canada," Reform Party of Canada, 1996. 142Act of Faith, 76, 80; Chris Adams, "The Reform Party and the Roots of Western Protest," in Canadian Politics 91/92, eds. Gregory S. Mahler and Roman R. March (Connecticut: Dushkin Publishing Group Inc., 1991), 176; Norm Ovendon, "Deficit, Unity Remain Reform's Key Cards," Edmonton Journal, 30 December 1995, G2; Dale Eisler, "Reform Says What Canadians Think," Calgary Herald, 15 December 1995, Al9. 143 Act of Faith, 11 0; Manning, viii; Trevor Harrison, Of Passionate Intensity (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1995), 146; "56 Reasons"; "Principles and Policies," 10; Assembly '96 affirmed the belief in provincial equality. 144McCormick, 345-346; Hugh Wmsor, "Reform Band Tunes up for Big Show," Globe and Mail, 4 May 1992, AI . 145Gruending, 202. 37 Charlottetown Accord, and publicly chastised NDP colleague Roy Romanow for supporting such reform. 146 The NDP's desire to abolish the Senate displays its apparent disinterest in enhancing the voice in Ottawa of other regions like the West, despite what the common people there have long demanded. Indeed, Ed Broadbent supported Prime Minister Trudeau's freeze on the price of western-owned oil and natural gas in the 1970s. This resulted in more than $60 billion of Western petroleum income being expropriated by the federal government (despite natural resources being a provincial jurisdiction), and spurred the creation of Western separatist movements. 147 Here, it seems that the NDP is captive to a Central Canada power bloc despite the common people elsewhere. Yet, the NDP may have been taking a more "national" view of Canada's resources by supporting Trudeau's move. It may have been representing the majority of common people outside the West on this issue, instead of only taking its cues from Westerners suspicious of any actions by Central Canada or Ottawa. Reform, in detesting such a measure, may seem captive to Western Canadian interests, despite many common people elsewhere. Thus, if Reform can accuse the NDP of being tied to Quebec, or Central Canada, then the NDP can charge Reform with appearing to be tied to a power bloc of Western Canada. Reform champions Senate reform and responds to feelings of Western alienation, it has only one seat east of Manitoba, and is unpopular in Quebec and the Maritimes. From its inception, however, Reform has aimed to be a national party. As well, Reform in 1993 finished second in 56 Ontario ridings.148 It may be on its way, then, to becoming a party with national support. Nevertheless, the vague definition of power bloc allows a populist party to target an "enemy." Yet, their political opponents can creatively accuse them ofbeing linked to other power blocs. Another perceived contemporary power bloc is to be a party favouring high-taxes.l 49 Today, many common people are fed up with taxes (even if they still expect constant levels of public service provision). However, the CCF-NDP has always believed that taxation is the 146Manning, 204; Delacourt, 107, 109, 110. 147Rick Hiebert, "Two Cheers for Direct Democracy," B.C. Report, 13 May 1996, 11. 148The Reformer. November 1993, 1. 149Alan Whitehorn. "The CCF-NDP and the End of the Broadbent Era," in Party Politics in Canada, ed. Hugh G. Thorburn (Ontario: Prentice-Hall Canada, Inc., 1991), 337. 38 solution for many of society's problems. With more public revenue through taxation, the NDP could redress inequality, create economic opportunity, and redistribute wealth and power more fairly.Iso This would allow the party to stop the "slash and burn" tactics of the other parties with their "attacks" on social programs that are a "war on the poor." Thus, Tommy Douglas in Saskatchewan established 600 new taxes and levies and increased 600 others during his administration, and his "free health services for all" promise required hikes in the sales, income and corporation taxes, along with annually increasing family premiums.Isi Ed Schreyer's Manitoba NDP raised personal and corporate income taxes to national highs while the importance of these sources as revenue in other provinces was declining.1s2 Saskatchewan NDP Premier Roy Romanow imposed tax hikes on everything from retail sales to cigarettes.I53 Bob Rae in Ontario racked up four billion in raised taxes during his 1990-1995 term.I54 The B. C. Harcourt NDP, according to B. C. Report newsmagazine, increased taxes by $670 million to cover an annual operating budget increase of more than $1 billion (5.7 per cent). ISS Selected Recommendations for the Reform ofthe System ofTaxation, the report that helped the B.C. NDP determine it's 1993 budget, advocated higher taxes on mcomes, inheritances, gifts, corporations, luxury goods, lottery winnings, accounting services, dry cleaning, restaurant meals, advertising, photocopying, golfing, sporting events, cultural events, architects, video rentals, accountants, civil and business litigation, wealthy seniors, and small businesses.156 For the 1993 federal election, the NDP promised a new two percent tax on business, a higher minimum corporate tax, more income tax for the wealthy (McLaughlin would raise it 13 per cent to 40 per cent, not including provincial income tax), and a new "Fair Wealth" tax on large net worths to access inherited or unearned wealth and capital. 157 For the next 150McLaughlin, 21, 22, 164; Broadbent, ix. 151Tyre, 18, 21-23, 29, 185, 211. 152McAllister, 41. l53Mark Nemeth, "Roy Romanow's NDP Wms a Second Term," Maclean's, 1 July 1995, 46. 154Jim Coyle, "Rae's Final Days in Ontario," Montreal Gazette, 28 February 1995, B3; Ehring and Roberts, xv, 304; Patrick Monallan, Storming the Pink Palace (Toronto: Lester Publishing Limited, 1995), 175. 155 Steve Vanagas, "A 'Revolting' Budget," B.C. Report, 12 April1993, 6. 156Vaughn Palmer, "Will the Middle Class Be Courted," Vancouver Sun, 2 February 1996, [page unavailable]. 157Julie Davis and Lome Nystrom, Vancouver Renewal Conference: Economic Policy Draft Discussion Paper, 1995, 10 [http://www.fed.ndp.ca]; "An NDP Sneak Preview," Maclean's, 11 March 1993, 40; Steve Vanagas, "Countdown to an Election," B.C. Report, 11 October 1993, 11. 39 federal election, the NDP promises more taxes on the rich for social programs. 158 All this has given the party a high-taxing reputation that makes it appear out-of-step with the contemporary populist mood. Of course, the precise extent to which the CCF-NDP is part of a high-taxing power bloc must be evaluated considering the taxing records of different Canadian governments and parties. Still, looking at the 23 countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development in the 1965-1983 period, David R. Cameron found that "leftist parties," moreso than "non-leftist parties," typically impose relatively high taxes--especially taxes on personal incomes and wealth. 159 The Reform Party thus plays up this high-taxing record of the NDP, to present itself, in populist fashion, as the most credible voice for the common people contemplating tax revolts. Reform promises to reduce or eliminate taxes and cut government spending, in areas including Parliament, government administration, grants to special interest groups, subsidies to business and political parties, and funding for bilingualism and multiculturalism. 160 Reform also pledged for the 1993 election to balance the budget in three years and eliminate the debt by cutting $19 billion in spending, or resign. 161 Of course, Reform only appears populist here, for promising fiscal responsibility. It must prove this populism in power (although voters have a guarantee with Reform's direct democracy, including recall). 3. CONCLUSIONS Few deny the populist nature of early agrarian movements like the CCF.I62 However, the CCF-NDP is not completely populist. 163 Populist parties trust and defer to the common people and have faith in democracy. Yet, tension exists between the CCF-NDP's education and central planning and these aspects of populism. As well, populist parties detest power blocs. The NDP 158"NDP Plays Old Song: Tax Rich," Prince George Citizen, 5 September 1996, [page unavailable]. 159oavid R Cameron, "Does Government Cause Inflation," in The Politics of Inflation and Economic Stagnation, eds. L.N. Lindberg and C.S. Maier (Washington: The Brookings Institute, 1985), 260. 160 "Principles and Policies," 14; Richard Mackie, "Manning Hears What Ontario Really Wants," Globe and Mail, 22 September 1993, A7; "Reform Rides No-Tax-Hikes Platform," Calgary Herald, 11 January 1995, A3 ; "56 Reasons." 161 "56 Reasons"; Flanagan, 127; "The Only Deficit Plan We've Seen," Globe and Mail, 23 September 1993, A18. l62J.F. Conway, "Populism in the United States, Russia and Canada," Canadian Journal of Political Science XI: 1 (March 1978): 119. 1630nly 1% of delegates to the 1983 B.C. NDP convention considered themselves populists. 52% of 1987 B.C. NDP convention delegates said they didn't "trust the simple, down-to-earth thinking of ordinary people rather than the theories of experts and intellectuals," while 60% of the electorate begged to differ. Whitehorn, "The New Democratic Party in Convention," 279, 290; Blake, Carty, and Erickson, 67, 133. 40 has joined several with constitutional links, even though it is not dominated by them. This misperception is due to the ambiguity of the definition of power bloc, and to the successful rhetoric of competing parties. Currently, the Reform Party is largely populist. The party has faith in the common people and tries to ensure their supremacy with direct democracy (that also displays the populist desire for changing the political system). As well, Reform works at not being connected to any power blocs. However, Reform ignores its own potential links to power blocs. It has also not had the opportunity as government to fulfill its promises and prove its populism. 41 CHAPTER THREE: BROKERAGE POLITICS, THE CCF-NDP AND THE REFORM PARTY 1. POLICY REVERSALS To broaden its electoral appeal, the CCF-NDP appears to have reversed many of its earlier policies. First, the NDP seems to have changed its attitude towards its old power bloc of capitalism. The number of negative references to capitalism slipped to one in the 1956 Winnipeg Declaration from 17 in the 1933 New Regina Manifesto. 1 The 1996 Party Principles document, despite calling for a "just and equitable distribution of wealth," does not mention capitalism. 2 Likewise, the NDP's 24 page 1988 election platform does not mention socialism. 3 Moreover, Ed Broadbent says that the debate between capitalism and socialism is over, that, "Market economies have been responsible for the production of more goods and services since the Second World War than were produced in all of human history." 4 Also, the Ontario NDP's 1979 "New Directions for Ontario's Political Economy" advocated improving international competitiveness and liberalizing trade--hallmarks of the "Right's" 1980s economic strategy.5 Second, the NDP now appears committed to reducing government when it often used to expand its size. Tommy Douglas tripled the size of the Saskatchewan bureaucracy when the population grew by only 70,000 (eight per cent). Ed Schreyer's Manitoban public service grew at twice the national average.6 Dave Barrett in B. C. increased the bureaucracy by 25 per cent when the population grew by ten per cent. 7 According to B. C. Report Magazine, Harcourt inflated that amount by 15 per cent, when other Canadian governments were cutting back. 8 However, the NDP record of government expansion must be compared to that of the other parties and to citizen demand and need for services. Yet today, the NDP looks at reducing the size of government. Bob Rae abandoned provincial car insurance and promoted privatizing other government property. 9 Glen Clark 1 Alan Whitehorn, Canadian Socialism (Toronto: Oxford University Press, 1992), 50. Partv Principles. New Democratic Party, 1996. 3 George Ehring and Wayne Roberts, Giving Away a Miracle (Oakville, Ontario: Mosaic Press, 1993), 219. 1an McLeod, Under Siege (Toronto: James Lorimer and Company, Ltd., 1994), 6. ~ and Roberts, xv, 63 . 6 James McAllister, The Government of Edward Schreyer (Kingston, Ontario: MeGill-Queen's University Press, 1984), 38. 7 Lorne J. Kavic and Garry Brian Nixon, The 1200 Days (Coquitlam: Kaen Publishers, 1978), 53. 8 Tom McFeely, "Actions Speak Louder than Words," B.C. Report, 29 April1996, 8. ~ and Roberts, xv, 305, 311. 2 42 vowed to reduce the public sector by 2,000 positions and promised $96 million in tax reductions that would, he claimed, enhance government efficiency. 10 The federal NDP now advocates decentralized forms of community involvement and local economic development in place of government being the service provider. 11 However, CCF-NDP government reduction could be a response to revenue shortfalls or a perceived inflated bureaucracy, not necessarily a policy reversal. These policy reversals make the CCF-NDP appear as a brokerage party. Instead of calling for major change and being a source of policy innovation, the party may now contribute to brokerage policy stagnation. It then appears ideologically ambidextrous. The NDP seems committed to assembling a voting coalition with more "centrist" policies to win power by bridging social cleavages. This often requires a charismatic, brokerage leader. However, it is one thing to appear brokerage with policy reversals, and another thing to be brokerage. CCF-NDP policy reversals may not compare with the records of the other parties. As well, many of these policy reversals occurred when the NDP was in power. It may be the constraints of public office that have forced the NDP to move away from its socialist origins. Besides, policy reversals may show that the CCF-NDP has become populist. It now represents issues that engage Canadians and recognizes that an ideology must change or recede into quixotic scholasticism and irreverence.12 These exceptions to the charge that the CCF-NDP has become brokerage through policy reversals show the difficulty in definitively characterizing a party as brokerage. The CCF-NDP has changed many of its policies. Yet, these actions do not necessarily indicate a shift to brokerage politics. Furthermore, the perception that the NDP has become brokerage could be due to the rhetoric of other parties. For instance, Reform has a relatively clean backtracking record. It thus tries to display its alleged purity by accusing the NDP of being brokerage. 10 Steve Vanagas. "The Looming Labour-Policy Showdown," B.C. Report. March 11 , 1996, 8; "Clark Sworn in Amid Scandal," Prince George Citizen, February 23, 1996, I. 11 Whitehorn, 247; Audrey McLaughlin, A Woman's Place (Toronto: Macfarlane Walter & Ross, 1992), 191 , Dave Barrett and William Miller, Barrett (Vancouver: Douglas & Mcintyre, 1995), 86. 12 Whitehom, Canadian Socialism, 13. "I became leader because people saw that we had to become more mainstream and broaden our base and get rid of a lot of the old dusty policies that were out of date" --Harcourt. 43 Indeed, Reform has only appeared to waffie on whether to support the Goods and Services Tax and the Charlottetown Accord. Yet, it came out on the populist side of both issues. Consequently, it seems to have usurped the CCF-NDP's role of providing a venue for voters disaffected with the standard brokerage parties with all their policy reversals. The party thus benefits by responding to popular alienation from politics as usual. 13 However, Reform may only have kept its promises because it has not had the opportunity to break them (although it supports recall as a guarantee). Unlike the older CCF-NDP, Reform has existed for only a decade. It has not faced the pressures of government that often result in parties scrapping their idealistic pledges in favor of "centrist" compromises. 2. EXPULSIONS AND PARTY DISCIPLINE Besides apparent policy reversals that might signal a brokerage image, the CCF-NDP has looked internally for ways to increase its appeal. First, the CCF-NDP does not always tolerate internal dissent. A few months after the founding of the CCF, the entire Ontario wing was disbanded by the national executive after farmers accused the labour section of being communists. 14 In the early 1950s, Ontario NDP leader Stephen Lewis expelled the League for Social Reconstruction (LSR) for its "extremism." The LSR included Frank Underhill, principal author of the Regina Manifesto, who then quit the party and likened it to a "sect whose leaders are mainly interested in maintaining at all costs their own authority within the sect. "15 Lewis then later expelled the provincial "Waffie" in 1972 for its "extremism. "16 Also in the early 1970s, federal NDP leader David Lewis banished the Quebec wing of the party that he feared had been taken over by separatists. 17 In 1969, the federal "Waffie" group of socialist New Democrats, including future leader Ed Broadbent, were purged by the NDP worried that their intemperance would divide the party and reduce electoral support. 18 The "Waffle's" precursor, 1 :navid Laycock, "Reforming Canadian Democracy," Canadian Journal of Political Science XXVII:2 (June I994): 2I4. ~ and Roberts, II ; Walter D . Young, Democracy and Discontent (Toronto: Ryerson Press, I969), 2. 15 Ehring and Roberts, I2. 16 1bid., II. 17 Jack MacDonald, "The New Democratic Party," in The Canadian Voter's Guidebook, [no editor given] (Toronto: Fitzhenry and Whiteside Limited, I972), 45. 18 Dennis Gruending, Promises to Keep (Saskatoon: Western Producer Prairie Books, I990), 56, 59. 44 the "Socialist Fellowship," formed in B.C. in the 1950s, was also banished by CCF leader MJ. Coldwell. 19 Second, the CCF-NDP has used party discipline along with expulsions to reduce the autonomy of its elected representatives. As a result, CCF-NDP MPs appear to owe their allegiance more to their party than to their constituents. Indeed, the founding convention of the B.C. CCF in 1935 restricted the independence of MLAs by stressing their accountability to the mass organization, and a special examining board was empowered to test their knowledge of socialism.20 Carrying on the West Coast tradition, cabinet solidarity in B. C. was mandatory under Dave Barrett. To oppose the government was dangerous, even though Barrett had trumpeted the merits ofthe U.S. legislative system where legislators are not as bound to vote on party lines. 21 Instead, party discipline was compulsory, free votes were rare, and a powerful speakers' committee supervised public speeches to ensure that members did not engage in utterances inimical to the party platform. 22 Later in B.C., Premier Harcourt fired cabinet minister Joan Smallwood who hinted that Harcourt should resign (which he did) for the "Bingogate" scandal. 23 In Saskatchewan a decade earlier, each Cabinet minister's report on nationalizing the potash industry had a different misspelling in it to allow NDP Premier Blakeney to trace leaks and know who to chastise. 24 Federally, Ed Broadbent promised disciplinary action for caucus dissension on the party's Meech Lake Accord position (as he did during the 1982 patriation process). He then stripped MP Ian Waddell of his caucus role as culture critic for opposing the Accord. 25 Later, leader Audrey McLaughlin castigated MP Svend Robinson for "interfering" in Jim Fulton's B.C. riding during a logging protest, and then removed finance critic Steven Langdon from his top position for publicly criticizing Bob Rae's deficit reduction plans.26 19 Judy Steed, Ed Broadbent: The Pursuit ofPower (Markham, Ontario : Viking, 1988), 142. 'l